Global Macroeconomic & Financial Scenario Outlook (2025–2029)

 

By M. Herzog (6. April 2025)

 

In this report for all our advisors and consultants of the IFC/IFB group, we outline a set of probability-weighted macroeconomic scenarios across three horizons – short-term (3–6 months), medium-term (2 years), and long-term (4 years) – for the United States, Europe, and Asia. Each scenario is built by synthesising several key themes in today’s macro-financial environment: the tension between central bank signalling and bond market expectations, the outsized role of asset prices (housing and equities) in driving demand, the influence of housing policies on perceived wealth and inflation, the impact of consumer psychology and media narratives on spending, the role of the offshore “Eurodollar” dollar system in global liquidity, safe-haven demand shaping yield curves, and the risks of misreading inflation data (drawing parallels with 2007–2009). We present a base case and at least two alternative scenarios for each horizon, with assigned probabilities, quantitative forecasts for key variables (inflation, growth, interest rates, asset prices, etc.), and regional narratives for the U.S., Europe, and Asia, noting interconnections and historical parallels. All values are in British English and monetary units as appropriate.

Actual Interrelations 

I. Central Banks vs. Bond Market Expectations 

Argument: Central banks are publicly uncertain about future economic developments. However, the bond markets—especially via the behaviour of the two-year yield—are acting with conviction, pricing in a deteriorating growth and inflation outlook.

Interpretation

  • While central bankers signal indecision, markets are showing clear directionality. 
  • This is evident in declining yields in the two-year part of the curve despite hot inflation prints (e.g., in Canada). 
  • The market is effectively “fighting the Fed,” declaring its view that the economic slowdown will force rates lower regardless of central bank hesitation. 


This divergence is key: the short end of the curve (which reflects central bank policy expectations) is pricing in cuts despite hawkish tones—suggesting a deep market conviction about economic fragility. 
 

II. Asset Prices as Economic Drivers  

Argument: Contrary to classical economic logic (where productivity drives wealth), in today’s economy, asset prices (housing, equities) drive economic perception and activity.

Analogy: a reversed hot-air balloon metaphor—asset prices are the balloon, the economy is the basket hanging beneath.

Implication

  • When housing or stock prices decline, consumer spending contracts, especially among high-income earners who dominate consumption. 
  • This effect feeds into macroeconomic weakness, reinforcing bond market expectations for falling rates. 

 

III. Housing Policy and Market Consequences 

Argument: Trump’s proposal to make housing more affordable by reducing regulation (rather than increasing subsidies) could reduce house prices, impacting perceived wealth and economic activity.

Macro Implication: 

  • Even beneficial policies (like deregulation) create short-term disinflationary pressures via reduced asset values. 
  • Lower nominal home values depress consumer balance sheets, echoing through demand and GDP. 

 
Reinforcement: This ties into bond market behaviour: policies aiming to reduce asset inflation (even with good intentions) are deflationary in effect. 
 

IV. Psychology and Media Narratives 

Argument: Consumer sentiment is profoundly shaped by media narratives, which are politically biased and influence economic behaviour.

Example: Democrats may now be less confident under a prospective Trump administration, reducing spending. In a fragile economic environment, this sentiment-driven reduction in aggregate demand can materially affect outcomes.

Conclusion: Psychological and media narratives are no longer noise—they are macroeconomic variables with causal weight in shaping demand. 
 

V. Eurodollar System and Bank Reserves 

Argument: The Eurodollar system functions outside the Fed’s reserve framework. Banks don’t need bank reserves to lend or settle transactions—they rely on internal credit creation and risk models.

Key Insight: 

  • There is no hard constraint on balance sheet capacity in the Eurodollar market beyond internal risk assessments. 
  • Bank reserves are largely irrelevant to lending and liquidity in this context, a major blind spot in central bank policy. 

 
Proof: From 1940 to 2007, bank reserves were flat (~$10B to $40B), yet global dollar credit exploded, demonstrating that reserve-based theories of money creation are obsolete. 
 

VI. Yield Curve Mechanics: Supply vs. Demand 

Argument: Many misinterpret rising Treasury supply as a guarantee of higher yields. In reality, the demand for safe, liquid assets (like Treasuries) often outpaces supply—especially in times of economic uncertainty.

Mechanism

  • Banks can borrow at ~1.5–2% (e.g., in Cayman-based Eurodollar banks) and buy Treasuries yielding ~4.15%—a low-risk arbitrage. 
  • This creates intense structural demand, absorbing issuance and keeping yields low despite fiscal expansion. 

 
Key Insight: The system is driven by risk-adjusted returns, not nominal yields. In volatile environments, a 4% Treasury might be preferable to a 10% private loan if default risk is too high. 
 

VII. Historical Parallels and Misinterpretations 

Argument: Bond market reactions post-rate cuts (e.g., in 2007–2008) often involve temporary yield spikes due to confusion and misread narratives. This has repeated in 2024–2025.

Clarification

  • In 2008, CPI surged from ~3.5% to 5.6% during recession, but the underlying trend was disinflationary. 
  • Similarly, today’s inflation scares may mask deeper deflationary dynamics, as reflected in yield behaviour. 

 

VIII. Conclusions and Macro-Level Synthesis 

  1. Market vs. Policy Discord: Bond markets are discounting growth and inflation far more aggressively than central banks, revealing a structural divergence. 
  2. Asset Prices Are Macro: Housing and equities now drive economic activity, not vice versa—making policy targeting asset bubbles fraught with deflationary consequences. 
  3. Eurodollar Dominance: The global banking system, particularly outside the U.S., creates and settles dollar liabilities without reference to reserves—explaining why reserve increases (e.g., QE) are often ineffectual. 
  4. Treasury Demand Is Structural:  Treasuries serve not merely as yield vehicles but as risk-adjusted stores of liquidity. This makes supply concerns largely irrelevant when demand is driven by systemic risk aversion. 
  5. Psychology is Macro: Narrative, sentiment, and perception (especially shaped by politics and media) now function as active macroeconomic forces. 


Now let us analyse several future scenarios

Probability Summary: For each horizon, we designate a Base Case (most likely) scenario alongside alternative outcomes. Probabilities are assigned to each scenario (summing to ~100% per horizon). These are subjective and meant to illustrate relative likelihood. The Base Case generally assumes a soft landing or moderate adjustment path. Alternative 1 often explores a downside (recessionary) risk and Alternative 2 considers an upside-inflation or stagflationary risk. In all scenarios, we incorporate market-implied expectations (such as yield curve pricing and options data) and fundamental data from sources like the IMF, BIS, and central banks.

Short-Term Scenarios (3–6 Months)

Horizon: Q2 2025 through Q4 2025 (roughly the next 3–6 months). The global economy at this horizon faces the immediate aftermath of the 2022–2024 inflation surge and policy tightening. Key issues include whether central banks will begin easing (as bond markets expect) or hold rates (due to inflation uncertainty), and how asset markets and consumers react in the very near term.

Base Case (≈60% probability) – “Soft Landing Underway”

Overview: In this base scenario, the global economy skirts a sharp recession, achieving a soft landing. Inflation continues to moderate gradually, and while growth slows, it remains slightly positive in the U.S. and near zero in Europe (avoiding a deep contraction). Central banks remain cautious but begin to pivot slowly toward easier policy in late 2025 as disinflation becomes clearer – aligning belatedly with bond market expectations for rate cuts. Asset prices experience a controlled correction rather than a crash: high valuations ease off but do not collapse, tempering excess demand without triggering a panic. Importantly, recent deregulatory efforts in housing (particularly in the U.S.) start to increase supply, cooling home price growth and modestly denting household wealth, which contributes to short-term disinflation. Consumers, while wary, do not retrench dramatically; improved sentiment emerges as media narratives shift from imminent recession to cautious optimism. The offshore dollar (Eurodollar) system remains liquid, helped by stable global dollar funding conditions, so global financial stress is limited. Yield curves stay partly inverted but begin to flatten as short-term yields fall in anticipation of policy easing. Policymakers avoid the mistake of overreacting to any one-off price spikes – mindful of 2008, when central banks tightened into a slowdown on misread inflation signals .

  • United States: Growth decelerates but remains positive: we forecast real GDP growth around +1% (annualised) for the next two quarters. Consumer spending slows from its earlier pace but is supported by a strong labor market and residual excess savings. Inflation (CPI) in the U.S. steadily declines towards ~2.5% year-on-year by late 2025 (from ~3-4% in early 2025), moving closer to the Fed’s target as supply bottlenecks have eased and prior rate hikes work through. Core inflation remains slightly above target (~3%), but the trend is downward. The Federal Reserve holds its policy rate steady around 4.5% through mid-2025, then considers a mild cut (~25–50 bps) by Q4 2025 as inflation clearly recedes. The Fed is cautious – officials stress they will “hold longer” until they are confident inflation is durably at 2%, reflecting the “higher for longer” rhetoric, but they also acknowledge that keeping rates too high while inflation falls could “mechanically” overtighten policy and weigh on growth . Bond markets remain convinced of eventual easing: the 2-year Treasury yield hovers around 3.5–3.8%, below the Fed funds rate, reflecting expectations of rate cuts on the horizon. (Indeed, as of April 2025 the 2-year yield is ~3.7% versus ~4.0% for the 10-year , indicating markets foresee easing ahead.) Long-term yields decline slightly with the improving inflation outlook – the 10-year Treasury yield slips to ~3.8–4.0%, down from ~4.2% earlier this year. The yield curve remains inverted but less so (the 10y–2y spread perhaps –0.2% now, versus –0.5% a few months ago), as short rates fall more than long rates. This partial un-inversion is consistent with historical patterns of inversion preceding recessions by about 12–18 months – but in this scenario, a major recession is avoided, making the current inversion a mild false alarm akin to 1998’s brief inversion. Housing market: With mortgage rates still elevated (~6–7%), U.S. house prices flatten or dip slightly (forecast –1% to –3% over 6 months). Crucially, policy efforts to boost housing supply (e.g. eased zoning and building regulations) begin to bear fruit: new housing construction increases, which in turn tempers home values. This perceived wealth reduction leads to a small negative wealth effect on consumption, helping to dampen demand and inflation in the short run – for example, a 2% quarterly decline in real house prices can reduce consumer spending by about 0.5% over two years . That said, lower housing costs improve long-run affordability. Equity markets: Stocks are choppy but avoid a bear market. The S&P 500 trades range-bound or with a slight upward bias (+5% to +10% over the period) as investor sentiment improves on cooling inflation and the prospect of future Fed cuts. Equity valuations, while still high, come down modestly as earnings catch up and discount rates remain relatively high. In other words, asset prices begin to reflect fundamentals a bit more than the liquidity-fueled gains of prior years – a welcome rebalancing. Consumer sentiment: After plunging to pessimistic levels during the inflation spike, U.S. consumer confidence starts to recover. With inflation pain easing and no recession materialising, indices like University of Michigan sentiment rise from recent lows. Media narratives pivot from “looming recession” to “soft landing achieved,” which boosts confidence. (Notably, research shows media recession talk can independently depress sentiment, so the fading of negative headlines itself removes a headwind.) We expect sentiment indexes to climb back toward long-run average levels over the next two quarters. Overall demand is thus sustained, albeit at a slower growth rate. The interplay of these factors – steady disinflation, stable asset markets, and resilient spending – keeps the U.S. on a soft-landing path in late 2025.
  • Europe (Euro Area): The Eurozone also experiences a mild slowdown without a severe recession in this scenario. High inflation from the 2022 energy shock is receding. We project Euro Area GDP to be roughly flat (0% to +0.5%) over the next 2–3 quarters – essentially stagnation, but avoiding a contraction thanks to improving real incomes and export demand. Inflation (HICP) falls, but remains somewhat above target; by end-2025 Eurozone headline inflation is ~2.8%, down from ~5% a year earlier, as energy prices stabilise and tighter monetary policy bites. Core inflation in Europe lags at around 3% (especially in services). The European Central Bank (ECB), having paused its hikes in 2024 after a peak deposit rate of ~4%, has already eased rates slightly to 2.5% by early 2025. In this scenario, the ECB likely pauses further cuts over the next 3–6 months, citing still-“unusually elevated” uncertainty and sticky core prices. However, by late 2025, with inflation clearly on a downward path, the ECB leans toward another 25 bps rate cut, bringing the deposit rate to ~2.25%. This indecision – wanting to ease, yet wary of inflation’s persistence – mirrors the Fed’s stance. Bond markets, meanwhile, have been pricing in additional easing: the 2-year German Bund yield gravitates toward ~2.0%, down from ~3% at the peak, anticipating ECB cuts. Long-term yields in Europe also ease; the 10-year Bund yield falls to ~2.3–2.5%. A strong structural demand for safe assets (from insurers, pension funds, etc.) in Europe helps cap long yields, irrespective of heavy government issuance – consistent with evidence that a stable safety preference keeps yields low even when debt is high. The Eurozone yield curve (e.g. 2s10s Bund spread) which had been mildly inverted, likely moves toward normalisation (spreads around 0%). Housing and assets: European housing markets, which saw rapid gains in 2021–22, cool considerably. Countries like Germany and the Netherlands, which had some froth, see price growth stall or turn slightly negative, contributing to a dampening of consumer exuberance (and thereby demand). European equities (e.g. STOXX 600) trade sideways; modest earnings growth and lower discount rates offset lingering growth concerns. Consumer psychology: European households are cautiously optimistic – falling headline inflation (notably in energy costs) lifts real incomes. However, uncertainty (war in Ukraine, global risks) keeps confidence only moderate. Governments are phasing out energy subsidies and normalising fiscal policy, which creates a mild fiscal drag but also signals reduced inflationary fiscal impulse. On balance, Europe muddles through the short term with neither boom nor bust – a welcome respite after the chaos of recent years.
  • Asia: The Asian outlook is mixed but generally improving in this scenario. China – Asia’s largest economy – sees a gradual recovery in the short term. After struggling with a property downturn and deflationary pressures in 2024, China’s government has shifted to stimulus mode: monetary easing (PBoC cut rates, reduced reserve requirements) and targeted fiscal support (infrastructure investment, housing support) are underway. We expect Chinas GDP growth to run about 4%–5% (annualised) in the second half of 2025, a bit below the government’s prior targets but an uptick from earlier in the year. Inflation in China remains relatively low (~2% YoY), as the economy is operating below capacity; the modest price gains give the PBoC room to ease policy further. Indeed, the PBoC might cut its benchmark loan prime rate by another ~25 bps to support credit. The global Eurodollar system benefits from China’s stabilization – increased Chinese liquidity and dollar funding needs are largely met domestically, meaning China is not drawing heavily on global dollar markets in stress. Other major Asian economies: Japan is a special case – the Bank of Japan likely ends its negative rate policy by 2025 and has tweaked Yield Curve Control (allowing 10-year JGB yields to rise modestly above 0%). In this base scenario, Japan’s inflation finally sustains around 2%, and the BoJ maintains 10-year yields around ~1% or below. Japanese investors continue to hold large amounts of U.S. and European bonds, though slightly higher yields at home mildly reduce their outflows. The continued structural demand from Asia for safe assets (FX reserves accumulation, etc.) remains a factor that helps keep global yields in check – a dynamic often referred to as the “global savings glut” or convenience yield on U.S. Treasuries. Emerging Asia (ex-China/Japan) – including India, ASEAN – generally sees solid growth in this scenario, on the order of 5% annualised, as domestic demand is robust and export markets (U.S., China) avoid recession. Their inflation has been trending down, allowing some central banks (e.g. Indias RBI, Bank Indonesia) to consider modest rate reductions to spur growth. Interconnected risks: Asia’s improvement feeds back positively to the West – for example, steady Chinese demand helps European luxury goods and Australian commodities, while not overheating prices. Likewise, the absence of a U.S. recession benefits Asian exporters. Overall, Asia acts as a stabiliser in the short term, adding a few tenths of a percent to global growth. Financial markets: Asian equity markets rise moderately (MSCI Asia ex-Japan up perhaps 5–8%) reflecting the better outlook. One risk to watch is global dollar liquidity: with the Fed not yet cutting much, some emerging markets could face dollar funding tightness, but in our base case the existence of Fed swap lines and ample FX reserves prevents any serious dollar shortage. The Eurodollar system, largely outside U.S. control, does not pose immediate problems – global dollar credit actually inched down slightly in late 2024, but stabilises by mid-2025. Should stress emerge, central banks are ready to deploy dollar swap lines as in 2020, reassuring markets. For now, global financial conditions in this scenario are neutral to slightly easing, supporting the soft landing narrative.


Bottom line (Short-Term Base Case): Through late 2025, the U.S. and Europe experience disinflation without deep recession, validating a soft landing. The Fed and ECB start aligning with bond market convictions of future rate cuts (though very gradually, so real rates rise initially as inflation falls). Asset prices adjust orderly – the economy proves to have been driven by asset wealth to a significant extent, but the correction in house prices (a few percent down) and equities (flat to modest gains) is enough to tame demand just enough. This scenario incorporates many positive outcomes (no major shocks, prudent policy, resilient confidence) and is our base case with about 60% probability. It reflects elements of the IMFs recent outlook where the U.S. achieves a soft landing and global growth holds around 3.2%. However, uncertainties are high, and we consider two prominent risks next.

Alternative 1 (≈25% probability) – “Recession Shock (Hard Landing)”

Overview: In this downside scenario, the economy tips into a recession within the next 3–6 months. Central banks’ indecision and lagged effects of tight policy result in an abrupt slowdown in demand. The bond market’s conviction of rate cuts proves correct – and in fact, cuts happen faster and deeper than in the base case, as policymakers scramble to respond to a sharper downturn. Asset prices, which have been propping up spending, finally crack: equity markets fall sharply and housing prices retreat, revealing underlying economic fragilities (weak productivity growth and high private debt) that had been masked by high asset valuations. Consumers and firms, spooked by persistent recession talk and perhaps a negative catalyst (e.g. a financial stress event or external shock), retrench en masse, causing a self-reinforcing downturn. This scenario sees clear echoes of 2008–2009, though the origins are different (this time stemming from policy over-tightening and sentiment shifts, rather than a banking collapse). Importantly, while a recession occurs, it is moderate in severity (not a depression), in part because authorities respond with stimulus and because banks – much better capitalised now – remain largely resilient, avoiding a full financial meltdown.

  • United States: In this scenario, U.S. GDP contracts for a couple of quarters. We forecast real GDP growth of roughly –2% to –3% (annualised) in Q3 and/or Q4 2025 – a mild recession by historical standards (comparable to, say, 1990–91 or 2001 downturns). The cracks start to show in consumer spending as excess savings are depleted and the cumulative hit of high interest rates squeezes borrowers. Consumer psychology plays a crucial role: after months of media warnings, households suddenly act on recession fears, significantly cutting back on discretionary spending (travel, durable goods). This validates the negative narratives and accelerates the downturn – a classic self-fulfilling prophecy where pessimistic media narratives cause aggregate demand to contract. At the same time, businesses, noticing softer sales and higher financing costs, curtail hiring and investment. Unemployment begins to rise; by late 2025 the U.S. unemployment rate could increase from ~3.5% to 5%+. Inflation: With demand evaporating, inflation decelerates rapidly. Headline CPI could fall to ~1.5–2% by early 2026, and core inflation would also drop closer to target (and possibly below on a short-term basis). This disinflation is faster than the Fed anticipated – essentially an overshoot of their goal due to the recessionary gap. An added disinflationary impulse comes from asset price declines: the wealth effect goes into reverse. U.S. equity markets fall into a bear market (e.g. the S&P 500 down ~20–25% from its recent peak) as earnings prospects dim and risk aversion spikes. Households experience a significant loss of wealth, given that equities and housing form a large chunk of net worth. Housing, which had been resilient, now softens materially – home prices nationally could decline on the order of 5–10% over the next year in this scenario, as rising unemployment and high mortgage rates choke off demand. (Certain frothy regional markets might see even steeper drops, reminiscent of 2008 albeit to a lesser degree due to undersupply this cycle.) This drop in housing wealth has a direct negative effect on consumption – consistent with estimates that a ~2% quarterly house price decline can cut consumer spending by ~0.5% over two years – and feeds a deflationary trend (housing disinflation in CPI). Federal Reserve response: Sensing the sudden downturn, the Fed pivots dramatically. They cut rates sooner and more aggressively than in the base case. By the end of 2025, the Fed could deliver on the order of 100–150 bps of rate cuts, bringing the Fed funds target down to ~3% or even lower if the recession is pronounced. (This aligns with hedging in interest rate futures that had reflected the possibility of a severe downturn requiring rapid loosening.) The Fed also pauses quantitative tightening; in a stress scenario it might even consider new QE or liquidity programs to stabilize Treasury markets and credit (much as it did in 2020). Bond markets rally strongly on the prospect of easier policy and flight-to-quality. The 2-year Treasury yield plunges (possibly to ~2.0–2.5%), its largest decline since the global financial crisis, as traders price in multiple Fed rate cuts and seek safety. The 10-year yield also falls, albeit not as dramatically – perhaps to ~3% or just below – reflecting lower expected inflation and a bid for long-duration bonds. The yield curve likely steepens significantly from its inverted state: with short rates collapsing, the 2y–10y spread could swing positive (say +50 bps), a typical pattern once the Fed starts cutting in a recession. Credit spreads, however, widen: corporate bond yields relative to Treasuries jump as default risks increase for weaker firms. Some highly leveraged sectors (e.g. speculative-grade corporates, commercial real estate borrowers) face a credit crunch. Financial system: While a 2008-style banking crisis is not our base assumption (thanks to stronger capital ratios – Tier 1 capital is far above 2007 levels – and proactive Fed liquidity support), we could see pockets of instability. For instance, a liquidity squeeze in the Eurodollar market might occur if foreign banks or shadow banks face dollar shortages. As much as $13 trillion in dollar obligations exist outside the U.S. banking system, and stress there could force the Fed to reopen swap lines broadly to provide dollar liquidity, as it did in 2008 and 2020. In this scenario, the Fed likely does so rapidly, mitigating the worst global funding stresses. Large U.S. banks remain solvent and liquid (no Lehman-style collapse), but smaller or weaker institutions could wobble under credit losses – potentially requiring targeted support (similar to the 2023 regional bank troubles, reemerging in a recession). Consumer sentiment and behavior: Consumer confidence falls to recessionary lows. The University of Michigan sentiment index, for example, could revisit depths seen in early 2022 (when inflation fears peaked) or worse, as unemployment news dominates headlines. Paradoxically, inflation moving down so fast might initially not register as a positive with consumers, who are more alarmed by job prospects. We essentially “talk ourselves into a recession,” as the adage goes. Policy response (fiscal): A U.S. recession in 2025 might prompt a fiscal response despite political gridlock – perhaps extended unemployment benefits or stimulus measures, especially with an election year approaching (if the political will exists). This could cushion the downturn somewhat by 2026, but in the 3–6 month horizon, the contraction is front and center.
  • Europe: The Eurozone is pulled into a downturn as well in this scenario. High energy costs and past ECB tightening have already sapped growth, so the U.S. hard landing pushes Europe outright into recession. We anticipate Euro Area GDP could shrink by –1% to –2% over the next two quarters (worse in manufacturing-heavy economies like Germany). Consumer spending in Europe drops as real incomes are squeezed not just by the past inflation, but now by rising unemployment and fear of job loss. Inflation: Eurozone inflation falls dramatically from its mid-single-digit rates. By late 2025, headline HICP might be near 2% or below, with core inflation following suit as the output gap widens. Countries like Spain or Italy, which saw higher inflation, could even see sub-1% inflation or brief deflation. The ECB reacts by halting any tightening plans and accelerating its easing: it might cut the deposit rate from ~2.5% towards 1% or lower in short order. (In 2008, recall, the ECB infamously hiked in July then had to cut rates rapidly by year-end; in this scenario, they avoid such a mistake and pivot to cuts earlier, learning from that episode.) Despite these cuts, the ECB also likely reactivates asset purchases or other tools if peripheral bond spreads widen. Given high debt levels in some European countries, a recession could reignite concerns about sovereign spreads (e.g. Italy). The ECBs Transmission Protection Instrument might be on standby to prevent unwarranted bond selloffs. Financial sector: European banks, like U.S. ones, are better capitalised now than in 2008, but a recession would increase non-performing loans. We might see isolated stress in smaller banks or those heavily exposed to real estate (for example, Swedish banks given Sweden’s property downturn). Overall, however, a systemic banking crisis is not assumed, though credit conditions tighten significantly. Asset markets: European equities drop ~20% in this scenario, in line with global risk asset moves. Housing markets in Europe, already cooling, turn downward; for instance, house prices in the Eurozone could fall ~5%+ on average, with larger declines in overvalued markets (e.g. German cities). This adds to the negative wealth effect and further chills consumer spending. Euro: In a global risk-off, the U.S. dollar typically strengthens. The euro could depreciate (perhaps falling from ~$1.10 to under $1.05) as investors flock to USD assets and as ECB rate cuts make the yield differential less attractive. A weaker euro might provide a small offset by boosting export competitiveness, though in a global recession export volumes suffer anyway. Sentiment and politics: Unemployment in Europe ticks up (e.g. from ~6.5% to 8% in the Eurozone), which could spark political pressures for stimulus. The European Commission might relax budget rules to allow fiscal loosening (much as they did during COVID). Nonetheless, Europe’s recovery usually lags the U.S., so even as the U.S. might bottom out in 2026, Europe could still be struggling. This short-term recession scenario for Europe has parallels to the 2008–09 crisis (when European GDP contracted sharply after the U.S.), but one key difference is the starting point: in 2008, European banks were loaded with U.S. toxic assets; now, the issue is more general demand shortfall, with banks in better shape. Also, inflation was low then, whereas now it’s coming down from high levels – so real interest rates actually rise initially as inflation falls faster than nominal rates, potentially deepening the recession (unless the ECB cuts very fast).
  • Asia: A U.S.-European recession inevitably dampens Asias outlook. China in this scenario likely misses its growth targets significantly. With Western import demand dropping, China’s export sector contracts, leading to spillover layoffs in manufacturing. If not already fully resolved, China’s domestic property troubles worsen as well – a global downturn reduces commodity prices and construction, further pressuring developers. We could see Chinas GDP growth fall to ~3% or lower in 2025, a “hard landing” by Chinese standards. In response, Chinese authorities unleash more stimulus: interest rates are cut aggressively (even though they’re already low), banks are instructed to lend, and the central government prepares fiscal expansion (perhaps large infrastructure projects or bailouts for the property sector). However, these measures take time, so China’s short-term trajectory is weak. Other Asian exporters (South Korea, Taiwan, Southeast Asia) also suffer from the global slump – e.g. Korea might enter a recession due to slumping electronics demand. Inflation in Asia: largely falls or stays low, as commodity prices likely plunge in a global recession. Oil could drop to, say, $50–60/barrel, which is a boon for energy importers like India but also a sign of weak global demand. Many Asian economies see inflation well below target (some flirting with deflation). Policy: Central banks across Asia pivot to easing. The Reserve Bank of India (RBI), for instance, might cut rates to support growth (especially if inflation there falls back into the 3-4% range). Even Bank of Japan, which has been trying to raise inflation, might postpone any tightening and maintain accommodative policy as global pressures intensify. One interesting aspect is the global dollar system: in a global recession, the dollar typically strengthens and dollar funding can dry up for emerging markets. Countries with high dollar debts (some Southeast Asian corporates, etc.) could face strain. But lessons from past crises mean many Asian economies now hold large FX reserves as a buffer (e.g. India, China, etc.). Additionally, the Fed’s swap lines can extend to major Asian central banks (BoJ, RBA, possibly PBoC indirectly through arrangements) to alleviate dollar shortages. We might see the IMF or regional arrangements (Chiang Mai Initiative) activated to assist vulnerable economies. Japan’s role as a capital exporter can also help: if U.S./EU yields plummet, Japanese investors may repatriate less, continuing to provide offshore USD liquidity. Asset impact: Asian stock markets fall broadly, with export-oriented markets down >20%. Chinese stocks might underperform given domestic and external woes. Currencies in emerging Asia likely depreciate against the USD, though those with strong external positions (like China’s RMB) might hold relatively steady or only slide modestly. Interconnected feedback: The global nature of this recession scenario means feedback loops amplify it – e.g. a U.S. import slump hurts China/Germany, which in turn hurts commodity exporters (Australia, Brazil) – a classic synchronous downturn. This has shades of the 2009 global recession, though perhaps milder in magnitude. A mitigating factor is that policymakers today would react faster with stimulus (having learned from the slow response in 1929 or even 2008). Thus, while Q3/Q4 2025 are painful globally, by 2026 there is a concerted global easing that lays ground for recovery (beyond our 6-month horizon).


Bottom line (Short-Term Recession): This hard-landing scenario carries ~25% probability. It is characterised by a policy overshoot – central banks kept rates high a bit too long such that, when combined with negative expectations, it triggers a recession. Bond markets end up vindicated (they correctly signaled the need for cuts with an inverted yield curve). Key variables would shift dramatically: global growth turns negative for a few quarters, unemployment rises, and inflation quickly converges to target or below. Central banks reverse course to cut rates aggressively (the Fed potentially back to near 0% by 2026 in this scenario). Importantly, asset price correction is central: housing and equity declines remove the artificial support under the economy, revealing weak underlying productivity (which had not kept pace with asset-driven “paper wealth” ). A balance sheet recession dynamic could take hold – akin to the post-2008 deleveraging or Japan’s 1990s, though hopefully milder given quicker intervention. In essence, this scenario is a manifestation of the downside risk if the wealth-driven expansion flips into a wealth-driven contraction. While painful, it is not as severe as 2008 because of stronger financial system safeguards (e.g. banks’ Tier 1 capital ~15% now vs <4% in 2007) and proactive monetary backstops.

Alternative 2 (≈15% probability) – “Stagflation Persistence” 

Overview: In this scenario, the global economy experiences a frustrating stagflationary impasse over the next 3–6 months. Inflation proves stubbornly high, refusing to fall to target as quickly as hoped, due to factors like resurgent commodity prices or entrenched wage growth. Central banks, facing uncomfortably high inflation, become indecisive about easing – in fact, they delay or cancel expected rate cuts, and some even contemplate further hikes. Bond markets, which had boldly priced in multiple cuts, are forced to reprice to a higher path for interest rates. This leads to an upward shift in yields (particularly at the short end) and a possible spike in long-term yields as well if investors demand a higher inflation premium – a dynamic reminiscent of mid-2008 when bond yields jumped on inflation fears even as growth was slowing. The result is a toxic mix: economic growth stagnates (or slows to near zero) under the weight of high interest rates and fading real incomes, yet inflation remains elevated (well above 2%). Asset markets struggle in this environment: neither a bull market (due to growth concerns) nor a full crash (nominal growth keeps corporate revenues growing in cash terms), but likely declining in real terms. This scenario bears similarity to the 1970s stagflation episode, though in a milder form (for now). Unlike the 1970s, central banks today have explicit inflation targets and more credibility – but that credibility is on the line here, as misreading inflation dynamics could prolong the pain. 

  • United States: Instead of continuing its downward trajectory, inflation in the U.S. plateaus or even ticks up slightly in the second half of 2025. For instance, headline CPI, which might have been ~3% in early 2025, could stall in the mid-3% range or climb back towards 4% by late 2025. Core inflation proves “sticky” around 3–4%, refusing to budge as services prices and wages remain robust. Possible drivers: a renewed surge in oil prices (say, due to geopolitical tensions in the Middle East) drives gasoline and transport costs higher; wage growth in a still-tight labor market runs near 5%, keeping core services inflation elevated; and inflation expectations among the public start to inch up, causing a wage-price spiral lite. The Fed, which had been hoping to start gentle rate cuts, is caught in a bind. Rather than cutting in late 2025, the Federal Reserve holds rates at the peak (≈4.5–5%) and even floats the possibility of another hike if inflation doesn’t improve. This stance surprises markets that had priced in easing – effectively the Fed is saying “not so fast”. The 2-year Treasury yield, which had fallen towards 3.7%, jumps back up to 4.3–4.5%, erasing the inversion gap with the fed funds rate. Long-term yields also rise because investors now see inflation staying higher for longer: the 10-year yield could rise toward 4.5–5% (levels not seen consistently since 2007), as an inflation risk premium gets embedded. The yield curve might flatten or even briefly revert to upward sloping, as short and long yields converge around 4.5%. Notably, this yield backup is happening even as growth is weakening – an atypical combination signaling stagflation. GDP and employment: With no monetary relief, economic growth slows to a crawl. We might see a quarter of near-zero growth or a very slight contraction, but not a deep recession yet – more like “growth recession” conditions. The unemployment rate could rise modestly (from ~3.5% to ~4–4.5% by end-2025) as interest-sensitive sectors (housing, manufacturing) shed jobs, but overall labor markets remain relatively tight by historical standards (as some industries still face labour shortages). The paradox is that despite weak growth, inflation stays high – so the misery index (inflation + unemployment) stops improving or worsens. Consumer sentiment: High inflation keeps sentiment depressed. Households feel the pinch of declining real incomes – wage gains are not keeping up with 4%+ inflation, and with asset markets underperforming, the wealth effect doesn’t help. Confidence surveys likely reflect considerable pessimism (comparable to early 2022 levels when inflation anxiety was peaking). Consumers start to behave in a more inflation-anticipating way – for example, making purchases sooner fearing prices will rise, which perversely can sustain demand and prices. Asset prices: Equities underperform significantly. The S&P 500 could decline or at best remain flat over 6 months, which in real terms is a loss given 4% inflation. Higher discount rates (with 10yr yields at 5%) compress equity valuations (P/E multiples fall). Corporate earnings might hold up in nominal terms (as companies can pass on some price increases), but margins could suffer from rising costs. Housing market: Housing affordability worsens further as mortgage rates rise in tandem with Treasury yields. We could see 30-year mortgage rates pushing 8%+. This essentially freezes the housing market – sales volumes drop sharply, new construction slows, and home price appreciation, which had already cooled, likely turns slightly negative nationally. However, given sticky inflation and general demand, we might not see a steep nominal drop in home prices, just stagnation (real house prices fall). One factor: many homeowners have low fixed-rate mortgages from prior years, so they don’t need to sell – this prevents a flood of supply. Thus, housing acts more as a stagflationary drag: low activity and persistent high rents (because would-be buyers stay renters). Indeed, shelter inflation could remain elevated in CPI in the short term because rent increases lag home prices (the “sticky rent” issue). Monetary policy credibility: The Fed’s predicament here is analogous to its 1970s dilemma or even mid-2008. In 2008, the Fed’s concern about rising headline inflation (due to oil) kept it from cutting rates aggressively until the crisis forced its hand; similarly, here the Fed’s priority on fighting inflation leads it to withhold stimulus despite economic malaise. The risk is a policy mistake – if the Fed misjudges and holds too tight for too long, it could eventually cause a deeper recession (as happened in the early 1980s when Volcker had to induce a sharp downturn to break inflation). In this 6-month window, though, they choose inflation-fighting over growth, meaning no immediate recession but prolonged stagnation. 
  • Europe: A stagflationary scenario in Europe might actually be worse than in the U.S., because the Eurozone is more exposed to commodity price swings and has less autonomous policy flexibility for member states. In this scenario, let’s say energy prices spike again going into next winter (for instance, a renewed natural gas shortage or oil price jump). Headline inflation in the Eurozone, which had been coming down, rebounds – perhaps climbing back above 4% (from ~3% prior). Core inflation in Europe also persists around 3%. The ECB, which had started easing, does an abrupt about-face. It stops further rate cuts and warns that it could even raise rates if inflation remains too high. This is a shock to markets and politicians alike, given growth is near zero. European growth indeed stagnates – we might see Eurozone GDP growth ~0% for the coming two quarters (or small negatives balanced by some positives). Countries like Germany could fall into a mild recession (contracting output) due to their manufacturing sector being hit by high input costs and weak external demand. Meanwhile Southern Europe might see slightly better activity due to tourism and fiscal support, but broad stagnation is the rule. Unemployment in the Eurozone, which had hit record lows (~6.5%), starts rising toward 7–8%, yet inflation doesn’t recede proportionally. This is the bane of stagflation. Bond yields: The German 2-year Schatz yield rises as markets price out ECB cuts – moving back toward ~3%. Peripheral bond yields (Italy, Spain) also rise; with growth stagnant, debt ratios look worse and investors demand a premium. The ECBs hawkishness, however, keeps the euro currency supported or stronger (in contrast to the recession scenario). A stronger euro (perhaps rising to $1.15 if markets believe the ECB will out-tighten the Fed) could slightly dampen imported inflation, but not enough. Fiscal policy: Governments in Europe face a dilemma – inflation is high (so they don’t want to stoke it with spending), but economies are weak (so they want stimulus). Likely there will be some targeted relief (e.g. energy subsidies if prices spike again) but also pressures to restore fiscal discipline given high debt and higher borrowing costs. This lack of a coordinated fiscal response means the burden falls on the ECB, which is in inflation-fighting mode. Social impact: Stagflation can breed discontent – we might see more labour strikes or wage demands (as in UK, France in 2023) because workers feel the cost-of-living crisis isn’t resolved. If wages do rise significantly in Europe (to compensate for inflation), it could further entrench inflation – a dynamic the ECB is keen to avoid. Thus a key risk is wage-price spiral: not an out-of-control one, but enough that inflation stays ~3-4%. Asset markets: European stocks decline, especially rate-sensitive sectors (utilities, real estate, tech). The STOXX 600 might fall ~10%+ over this period. European house prices, already stretched in some countries, start to decline in real terms. In nominal terms, some markets might plateau (like France, Germany), but in high-inflation countries nominal prices could even still rise modestly, masking real declines. Banks in Europe could face margin pressure: higher rates help net interest margin, but if loan demand is weak and defaults edge up, it’s not clearly beneficial. They also hold sovereign bonds, which are losing value as yields rise (though accounting rules and hold-to-maturity portfolios may cushion immediate hits). Overall, Europe in stagflation sees little relief – it’s a situation of “no growth, still-high prices,” which is politically and economically hard to navigate. 
  • Asia: Asia’s outcome in a stagflationary scenario depends on whether the inflation is global commodity-driven and how each country is positioned. Oil-importers like China, Japan, India would face the pain of higher import costs. China might see its inflation finally perk up (which ironically the PBoC might welcome to a point, given recent deflation fears). If oil is up and global inflation high, Chinas CPI could rise to ~3% or more, constraining PBoC’s ability to ease further. Yet China’s growth might not benefit much from global demand (since U.S./EU are stagnant). So China could face its own version of stagflation: moderate inflation despite sub-par growth. The government might resort to more direct stimulus (which could then risk further inflation or debt problems later). Japan: higher commodity prices push Japan’s inflation above target again (perhaps 3%+), which might actually help firmly exit deflation psychology, but if it’s purely cost-push, it hurts consumers. The BoJ in this scenario might end Yield Curve Control and allow rates to rise a bit to anchor inflation expectations – but it will tread carefully to avoid choking the fragile growth. Emerging Asia: many ASEAN countries are also oil/gas importers (except Malaysia). They would experience higher inflation, which could force their central banks to maintain tight policy even as growth slows. India, for example, could see CPI stick around 6% (above RBIs comfort) due to costly imports, limiting its rate cut space and keeping growth below potential. Trade flows: If the U.S. and Europe are not in outright recession (just stagnation), Asian export volumes might not collapse, but they won’t grow briskly either. The benefit Asia saw from supply chain normalization fades, and instead they face a lukewarm external environment with possibly rising input costs. Commodity producers in Asia (like Indonesia for coal/palm oil, Malaysia for oil/gas) could actually see some benefit – their export revenues rise with prices, which might improve their trade balances but also fuel domestic inflation and possibly Dutch disease effects. Global dollar dynamics: In stagflation, the US dollar might not follow its usual recessionary strengthening path. If U.S. inflation is high and Fed not easing, the dollar could remain relatively steady or even weaken against some currencies (investors might diversify into currencies of countries handling inflation better, or into gold/commodities). Emerging markets with high inflation and weak growth could face stagflationary debt risks – unlike a pure recession scenario where the IMF can prescribe stimulus, in stagflation policy choices are tougher. Debt-laden countries might face rising borrowing costs and reluctant lenders, raising risk of sovereign stress in some frontier markets (e.g. some South Asian economies or highly indebted ones). We might see more reliance on the IMF or bilateral support in this scenario for vulnerable nations. 


Bottom line (Short-Term Stagflation): This scenario (~15% probability) is essentially a “higher-for-longer” world where inflation doesn’t behave as forecast, forcing central banks to maintain or even increase tight policy, thereby strangling growth but not yet defeating inflation. Key variables: Inflation stays ~3.5–4.5% in advanced economies (above target), policy rates remain near current peaks (Fed ~4.5–5%, ECB ~3–4%) instead of falling, GDP growth stagnates ~0%, unemployment rises modestly, 10-year yields rise (US ~4.5–5%), yield curves flatten (no inversion as both short and long rates high), equities decline ~10–20%, and housing stagnates with very low sales. In many ways, this is a “pick your poison” scenario akin to what McKinsey termed “higher for longer” – not as catastrophic as a crash, but a prolonged period of subpar economic performance and above-target inflation. Historically, the late 1970s is a parallel (inflation stayed high until a severe policy action caused recession). A crucial difference now is central banks’ determination not to let 1970s-style spirals take hold – so one might consider this stagflation scenario as a transitional phase that, if it persisted, would eventually provoke an even stronger central bank response (possibly leading to a recession beyond our 6-month horizon if needed to finally tame inflation). Thus, stagflation in the short term could simply be delaying an eventual hard landing, unless some positive supply-side developments intervene (e.g. productivity boost or resolution of supply chain issues) to bring inflation down benignly. 

Short-Term Scenarios Summary: In sum, our short-term outlook spans (1) a base case of soft landing (decent chance), (2) a downside recession (significant risk), and (3) a stagflation scenario (less likely, but possible). Each has distinct implications: the base case implies moderate policy easing later in 2025 with inflation nearly tamed; the recession case implies rapid easing and a reset of asset valuations (and would be a prelude to recovery starting from a lower base); the stagflation case implies protracted tight policy and unresolved inflation, making the eventual policy choices more painful. These short-term scenarios set the stage for the medium-term trajectories we discuss next.

(For a quantitative snapshot, see Table 1 below, which summarizes key forecasts under each short-term scenario.)

Medium-Term Scenarios (2 Years Out) 

Horizon: Through ~2027 (the next 24 months). By this horizon, the immediate cyclical dynamics play out and more structural trends come into focus. We explore how the short-term scenarios could develop over the medium term. The U.S., Europe, and Asia may diverge more depending on regional fundamentals. Key uncertainties include the persistence of inflation or deflationary forces, the cumulative effects of monetary policy shifts, fiscal and productivity developments, and how financial markets and the global banking system adjust to the new equilibrium. We present a Base Case of a mild cycle (soft landing leading to moderate recovery), an Alternative 1 where the recession in the short term leads to a prolonged slump (slow recovery or “lost years”), and an Alternative 2 where stagflation persists and possibly forces a late hard landing or continued stagnation. Each scenario integrates market pricing (e.g., forward curves for 2026–27) and fundamental indicators (like IMF medium-term forecasts, output gaps, etc.), along with historical analogies (the late 2000s recovery, the post-1970s period, etc.). 

 

Base Case (≈55% probability) – “Mild Recession & Recovery (Soft Landing Extended)” 

Overview: In the base medium-term scenario, the global economy navigates the next two years without major calamities, experiencing either a very mild recession or none at all, followed by a period of moderate growth and re-anchored low inflation. Essentially, the soft landing either holds or at most there is a shallow downturn in 2025–2026 that paves the way for a healthier expansion by 2027. Central banks in this scenario successfully pivot to a neutral stance without igniting a new inflation surge or a severe slump – a feat of policy finesse. Asset prices, after an initial wobble, stabilise and begin to rise more in line with fundamentals (supported by improving productivity and earnings, rather than just liquidity). Productivity growth shows tentative signs of improvement, helped by recent investments (e.g., digitalisation, AI, supply chain diversification) – this is crucial, as it allows economies to grow a bit faster without inflation. Housing markets benefit from increased supply, keeping affordability in check and inflation low, while no longer being a speculative driver of growth. In many respects, this scenario resembles a return to a Goldilocks environment by 2027: steady growth of ~3% globally, inflation of ~2%, and interest rates back to more “normal” pre-2010s levels (but not ultra-low). It aligns with what McKinsey’s long-term analysis calls a “productivity acceleration” scenario that catches up with balance-sheet expansion – though we assume only modest productivity gains, not a full boom. 

  • United States: After navigating 2025 without a hard landing (or with just a brief, shallow contraction in early 2026), the U.S. economy finds itself in a better equilibrium by 2027. GDP growth for 2025 as a whole might come in around ~2% (helped by a strong first half in the soft-landing case), slow to perhaps 1% in 2026 (as tighter policy works through), but then rebound to ~2.5% in 2027 as headwinds recede. This averages out to a moderate expansion, slightly below the historical trend but solid given demographics (the working-age population growth is low). Unemployment, which may have risen slightly to ~4–5% at its worst, falls back toward 4% by 2027 – essentially “full employment.” Inflation: The Federal Reserve is largely successful in returning inflation to target. Headline PCE/CPI inflation is around 2.0–2.2% in 2026 and 2027, and importantly, inflation expectations remain well anchored at 2%. The lessons of the 1970s are heeded – once inflation is down, the Fed doesn’t let it flare up again. One reason inflation stays low is that asset-driven demand excesses have abated: by 2026, consumer spending growth is more in line with income growth, not turbocharged by wealth effects. Also, housing supply improvements (fostered by deregulatory initiatives started earlier) contribute to keeping shelter inflation subdued or even negative. For instance, if U.S. housing supply growth outpaces the population for a couple of years, rent inflation could be negligible, a significant relief given the shelter’s CPI weight. Federal Reserve policy: Having likely cut rates modestly in late 2025 (in the soft-landing scenario) or more aggressively if a mild recession emerged, the Fed 2026 has settled at a neutral policy stance. By 2027, the Fed funds rate might be around 2.5%–3.0%, which we interpret as the new neutral (slightly positive real rates, assuming ~2% inflation). The Fed might even start thinking about raising or lowering depending on conditions, but in our base case, inflation and growth are balanced so the Fed can hold rates steady through 2027. Importantly, the bond market forward curves align with this: the yield curve likely un-inverts and steepens in 2026 as cuts happen, then perhaps flattens at a gentle positive slope by 2027. For example, by 2027, we could see the 10-year Treasury yield ~3.0–3.5% and the 2-year ~2.75%, a normal upward slope reflecting stable growth and inflation expectations. This is consistent with a world where safe asset demand keeps long rates structurally a bit lower than nominal growth – a continuation of the pre-2020 “low r*” environment albeit at a slightly higher level. Fiscal and debt: The U.S. fiscal situation in this scenario is manageable. The recession (if any) was mild, so the debt-to-GDP didn’t explode and interest costs, though higher than in the 2010s, remain sustainable given the return of growth. If anything, lower interest rates by 2026–27 ease debt service somewhat after the spike in 2024–25. There might be some fiscal consolidation debate, but with a decent economy and low rates, the pressure is not acute. Asset markets: By 2027, equities likely resume an upward trajectory, underpinned by earnings growth rather than P/E expansion. The S&P 500 could reach new highs by 2027 in nominal terms. Over 2025–27, one might expect average annual total returns in U.S. equities of, say, mid-single digits (consistent with earnings and GDP growth). Valuations: If inflation is low and stable, equity risk premiums might normalise. We could see a world of moderately high valuations, not extremes: perhaps the S&P 500 trading around 18–20x earnings (versus 22–25x at peaks), thanks to lower risk-free rates and confidence in stability. Housing: U.S. housing likely stabilise in 2026 after the 2024–25 cooling. By 2027, with mortgage rates back down to perhaps ~5% (given 10-year yields ~3-3.5% plus spread) and better balance in supply-demand, housing activity picks up. House price growth might resume at a modest pace in line with income growth (e.g. 3–5% YoY by 2027) – avoiding both the bubble dynamic and a crash. Essentially, housing becomes more of a productive sector (through construction) rather than an investment mania. Consumer behaviour: In this benign medium term, consumers benefit from solid wage growth (maybe 3–4% annually) and low inflation, leading to real income gains. Consumer sentiment likely become optimistic by mid-2020s standards. For example, the University of Michigan index could be regularly in the 80s or 90s (on a 100 scale) if people feel the economy is in a “good place” (contrast this with readings in the 50s during 2022’s inflation angst). One factor that could improve sentiment is if media narratives shift to highlight the success in taming inflation and maintaining employment – a positive narrative reinforcing spending (the opposite of the gloom loop earlier). Productivity and supply side: A critical assumption in this base case is that productivity growth rises from the anaemic ~1% of the 2010s towards maybe 1.5–2% by 2027. Early signs include accelerated digitalisation (the pandemic pushed firms to do more with fewer workers), adoption of AI in white-collar tasks, and a revival of business investment once uncertainty abates. Indeed, there’s evidence that higher interest rates might have encouraged more productive allocation of capital by discouraging cheap debt-fuelled unproductive investments. If even a modest “AI boost” occurs, it could raise output while holding down costs – thus non-inflationary growth. This would be the “Goldilocks” ingredient that differentiates this scenario from stagnation: supply potential improves just as demand is managed, letting the economy grow faster without inflation. (It’s somewhat speculative, but not implausible given technological momentum and reshoring of some industries which could initially be costly but later add to capacity.) 
  • Europe: In the medium-term base case, Europe also enjoys a period of recovery, though typically the Eurozone’s growth in our scenario is a bit weaker than the U.S. due to structural constraints. After near-stagnation in 2024–25, the Eurozone could see a small technical recession or very slow growth in 2025–26, followed by a moderate pickup by 2027. We project Euro Area GDP growth averaging about 1.5% per year over 2025–2027 – lower than the U.S. but an improvement from near zero. Some of this growth is supported by fiscal tailwinds as countries deploy EU NextGenerationEU funds in investments (green and digital transitions). Inflation: The ECB succeeds in bringing inflation back to target. By 2026, Eurozone inflation will be back near 2%, and it will stay there in 2027. Inflation expectations (e.g. from ECBs Survey of Professional Forecasters or market 5y5y swaps) re-anchor at 2%. This stability in prices is critical for Europe, given its populace’ sensitivity after the recent high inflation (the worst since the euro’s creation). ECB policy: The ECB in this scenario likely lowered rates into 2025–26 to cushion the slowdown (perhaps deposit rate down to ~1% or so). As the economy finds footing and inflation is low, the ECB holds at a neutral rate of ~1.5–2% by 2027 (slightly below the Fed, reflecting lower trend growth in the Eurozone). The ECB might also slowly reduce its balance sheet (QT) without market disruption, given calm conditions – but likely keeps a larger balance sheet than pre-2020 for financial stability reasons. Fiscal policy and EU: Some reforms and investments take shape that help Europe’s supply side. For example, European energy policy adjusts after the 2022 shock – by 2027 there’s more LNG infrastructure, renewables and storage have scaled up, reducing energy price volatility and dependence on imports. This helps keep inflation low and improves industrial competitiveness. Labour market reforms in some countries (and improved migration flows) ease worker shortages. All told, Europe makes slow but forward progress on structural issues. Unemployment in the Eurozone, which may have risen to ~7-8% in a slump, comes back down to ~6-7% by 2027. Asset prices: European equities are likely to recover alongside global markets, although returns may lag the U.S. slightly due to the heavier weight of old-economy sectors. European housing markets, after cooling, resume modest growth as well. Notably, if interest rates in Europe stabilise low, housing could pick up by 2027, but given the policy focus on avoiding another affordability crisis, there may be macroprudential measures keeping mortgage lending in check. Currency: The euro in this benign scenario might be relatively stable in the mid-$1.10s. With both the Fed and ECB at neutral, with no huge interest differential, the EUR/USD is driven by relative growth. Possibly the dollar might weaken a bit by 2027 if global risk sentiment is strong (often the USD falls in good times), so the euro could be stronger, but within a moderate range. Interconnectedness: A healthier Europe by 2027 benefits from and contributes to the global stable scenario. For example, European banks – having navigated the prior period – are in decent shape and can extend more credit, including to emerging Europe and Africa. The Eurodollar market and global liquidity are ample: European banks can raise dollar funding easily to on-lend abroad (helping those reliant on offshore dollars). The BIS global liquidity indicators might show a renewed expansion of cross-border credit by 2027 after the lull, reflecting confidence and a search for yield. 
  • Asia: In the base medium-term scenario, Asia continues to be a growth leader. China manages to execute a controlled rebalancing: after a subpar 2024–25, it shifts to a more sustainable growth path. We expect China’s growth to average around 4–5% in 2025–27 – lower than the pre-2020 6%+, reflecting demographics and structural slowing, but stable. Crucially, China addresses some domestic issues: it restructures key property developers and local government debts, albeit gradually, preventing a financial crisis. It also pivots more to consumption-led growth, which is slower but steadier. Inflation in China remains low (~2%), giving room for an accommodative policy. By 2027, the PBoC likely keep interest rates relatively low and currency management stable (the yuan may gradually internationalise a bit more, but not challenging the dollar yet). Other emerging Asian economies (India, Southeast Asia) enjoy solid expansions, with India possibly growing ~6% and ASEAN around ~5% annually, barring external shocks. These economies benefit from supply chain diversification (the “China+1” strategy means more investment flows to Vietnam, India, etc., boosting medium-term growth) and relatively young populations (for India/Philippines) supporting demand. Japan in this scenario might finally see slightly higher steady inflation (~1.5-2%) with moderate growth of ~1%, which is an improvement for them. The BoJ likely ended negative rates and may have a slightly positive policy rate by 2027, but still very accommodative relative to others. Global trade and investment: A stable macro environment by 2027 allows for a modest revival in global trade growth (after the supply shocks and geopolitical tensions caused some fragmentation earlier). While we don’t assume a reversal of deglobalisation, companies have adapted with more resilient supply chains, and trade flows resume growing roughly in line with GDP. Asia, being the manufacturing hub, benefits from this. Commodity markets: In the base case, commodity prices are moderate – not crashing (because global growth is decent) but not spiking (because no supply war and because investments in energy transition are paying off). For example, oil might be in a middling range (e.g. $60–80/bbl) and gradually less macro-critical as EV adoption rises. This stability helps both consumers and producers plan better. Financial stability: By 2027, the combination of sounder bank balance sheets, measured credit growth, and lack of extreme imbalances will lead to relatively few financial crises globally in this scenario. Regions like Southeast Asia, which in the 90s had a crisis, remain stable thanks to learned prudence (better reserve buffers, less USD mismatch). The Eurodollar system—the offshore dollar credit—expands in a healthy way to meet global trade financing needs and is backstopped effectively by central bank cooperation if needed. Overall, Asia in the base case adds a lot to global growth and also becomes more integrated: initiatives like the Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership (RCEP) take effect, boosting intraregional trade. 


Bottom line (Medium-Term Base): The base medium-term scenario is one of recovery and re-convergence to stable growth by 2027. It implies that the inflation shock of 2021–2023 is firmly behind us, and a combination of prudent policy and a bit of good fortune (no new big shocks) has kept the economy out of a deep bust. Fundamentals start to matter more again: productivity, labour force growth, and investment drive growth, rather than asset booms or busts. Probabilistically (~55%), this is our central outlook: a mild cycle that results in inflation of ~2% and global growth of ~3% by 2027 (with U.S. ~2%, EU ~1.5%, China ~4.5%). In many respects, it’s like a return to the pre-2008 “Great Moderation,” albeit with higher public debt and slightly higher interest rate levels than the 2010s, but manageable. The main caveat is that this scenario requires no major policy mistakes and some improvement in the supply side (so that the arguments about asset-driven economies start to fade as productivity picks up). If those conditions falter, the alternatives below may materialize. 

Alternative 1 (≈25% probability) – “Prolonged Slump (Balance Sheet Reset)” 

Overview: In this adverse medium-term scenario, the world experiences a prolonged period of subpar growth – essentially a drawn-out hangover from the excesses of the past decade. If a recession occurred in 2025 (as in the short-term Alt 1), its aftermath lingers and recovery is weak and halting. Even if a hard landing was avoided, growth remains sluggish (“secular stagnation” vibes). This could be due to several reinforcing factors: private sector deleveraging (households and firms repairing balance sheets after asset price declines), credit constraints (banks become more risk-averse, lending less), and possibly persistent global uncertainties (geopolitical tensions, trade fragmentation) that dampen investment. Inflation in this scenario falls and stays too low, even below target – raising the spectre of deflation in some regions, akin to the post-2008 or post-1990 Japan environments. Central banks find themselves re-running the post-GFC playbook: rates back near zero, quantitative easing reintroduced or expanded, and pleas for fiscal policy to help. However, high public debt and political fatigue limit fiscal expansion, so the economy muddles through. This scenario aligns with what McKinsey described as a “balance sheet reset” or Japan-like outcome, where asset values are sharply correct (30%+ down from the peak) and leverage is slowly unwound, resulting in a lost half-decade of sorts. It’s essentially the realization of the downside risk that the base case avoids – a world where the bill from the 2020-2021 asset boom and pandemic stimulus comes due in the form of an extended sluggish period. 

  • United States: In the prolonged slump scenario, the U.S. might have entered a recession in 2025 and struggled to regain momentum through 2026 and 2027. Real GDP growth could average only ~0–1% per year in 2025–27, meaning by 2027 output is far below the pre-2024 trend. The unemployment rate might rise and then stick around 6–7% for several years – a significant labour market slack reminiscent of 2010–2013, when joblessness was high and took a long time to come down. Consumer behaviour: Households, scarred by declines in stock portfolios and home equity, focus on saving and debt reduction. The personal saving rate, which was very low during the asset boom, jumps back up. For example, if pre-recession it was ~3%, it might rise to 8%+, reflecting a more cautious consumer. This depressed consumption relative to income contributes to slow growth. Wealth effect reversal: By 2027, U.S. equity indices might still be below their 2024 peaks in this scenario. Suppose the S&P 500 fell 30% in the recession and only partially rebounded – it could easily be, say, 15% lower than the peak even after some recovery. House prices might also not regain their highs; down 10–15% from the top and then flat. Consequently, net wealth relative to GDP falls significantly (a kind of “wealth reset” ). This is a healthy correction to valuations that were out of line with productivity, but it brings a negative demand impulse each year as people adjust to feeling less wealthy. Investment: Businesses are reluctant to invest in new capacity with so much uncertainty and slack demand. Private fixed investment could be quite subdued; capacity utilisation stays low. Perhaps only government and green energy investments provide some support. Inflation: With chronic output gaps, inflation likely falls below 2%. By 2026 and 2027, U.S. core inflation could be ~1% or even less, flirting with deflation in some sectors. Commodity prices would likely be low (oil perhaps $50 or lower, given weak demand), further pulling down headline inflation. This is a flip from the recent experience and more like the 2009–2015 era, where the Fed was more worried about too-low inflation. Fed policy: The Federal Reserve in this scenario cuts rates all the way back to the effective lower bound (around 0% or maybe slightly above if they keep a floor). By 2026 the Fed could be at 0–0.25% again and undertaking new rounds of quantitative easing (QE) to stimulate the economy and keep long-term yields down. Given that inflation is no longer a threat, the Fed’s concern pivots fully to supporting the recovery and avoiding deflation. For instance, the Fed may buy Treasuries and mortgage-backed securities to push mortgage rates down and try to revive housing. They might even explore more unconventional tools if needed (forward guidance that rates will stay zero for longer, or facilities to support credit flow to SMEs). Bond market: Yields in the U.S. would be very low across the curve. The 10-year Treasury yield could fall to, say, 1.5–2.0% and remain in that vicinity – reflecting a combination of low inflation, Fed QE, and heavy demand for safe assets in a risk-averse climate. The yield curve might steepen off the absolute floor but overall remain fairly low (e.g., 2-year ~0.5%, 10-year ~1.5% gives a +1% spread – a normal but low-yield curve, similar to early 2000s or early 2020s). Credit conditions: Despite low risk-free yields, borrowing might not surge because banks tighten lending standards (wary of defaults) and borrowers are not keen. We could see a phenomenon like the post-2008 credit crunch: loan growth stays sluggish. Some sectors with high leverage (energy, real estate developers, etc.) might go through bankruptcies, and banks nurse their loan books carefully. On the positive side, the financial system as a whole does not implode – thanks to regulatory capital, etc., big banks survive, but they aren’t expanding credit dynamically either. Fiscal space and policy: A slow economy and low interest rates may tempt fiscal policymakers to do more stimulus. However, by 2026–27, public debt will be higher (due to low growth and whatever deficits incurred during the recession). Political appetite might be limited for large new spending (especially if a lot was done in the pandemic and if a divided government prevails). We might see some incremental infrastructure or industrial policy spending (perhaps both parties can agree on competitiveness investments), but not a big New Deal. So fiscal is mildly supportive at best, not a game-changer. That puts more onus on monetary policy which is largely spent at ZLB – a classic liquidity trap scenario. Consumer sentiment: Extended weakness means confidence stays fragile. There could be a sense of economic malaise as in the early 1990s or 2010s when people felt the economy was not delivering for them. If unemployment is persistently high, public dissatisfaction could rise, influencing politics (possibly more support for populist or radical policies, which itself creates uncertainty). Parallels: This draws strong parallels with the U.S. post-2008 recovery, which was the slowest on record – except now debt levels are higher and policy space is more constrained. Also a parallel with Japans Lost Decade (1990s) – where a property and stock bust led to chronic low growth and deflation. The U.S. may avoid outright deflation thanks to its dynamic private sector, but stagnation is a risk. 
  • Europe: Europe in a prolonged slump scenario likely fares worse than the U.S. (as was the case after 2008, when Europe had a double-dip and long stagnation). If the Eurozone had a recession in 2025, by 2027 it might still be basically at the same level of output as pre-recession. We project Euro Area growth averaging ~0–1% annually, meaning essentially no real growth per capita for a few years. Unemployment could rise to 9–10% (particularly if fiscal austerity re-emerges, as it mistakenly did in early 2010s Europe). Inflation: Likely undershoots the ECBs 2% target consistently. Europe is prone to deflation in such scenarios (indeed, core inflation was 0-1% in the mid-2010s). We could see HICP inflation around 0–1% in 2026–27 if slack is large and energy prices are low. Several peripheral countries might experience outright price declines. ECB policy: The ECB would reverse its course fully to stimulus. By 2026, expect the ECB to have cut the deposit rate back to 0% or negative again if deflation threatens. They would likely restart QE (asset purchases), potentially including expanding corporate bonds or even equity purchases (as the Bank of Japan did) if needed to support markets. There might be new rounds of TLTROs (targeted long-term refinancing operations) to push banks to lend. However, with rates at zero and the balance sheet bloated, the ECB is back in the same quagmire as the 2014–2019 period. Fiscal: The EU might relax its budget rules initially in the recession, but if government debt soars (Italy could approach 160-180% debt/GDP in a deep slump), pressure returns to consolidate, risking a replay of austerity that further depresses growth. Possibly the EU does more joint funding (like NextGenEU 2.0) to invest and stimulate, but political consensus is tough. Without strong fiscal help, Southern Europe could languish with high unemployment (Spain, and Greece in the early 2010s style). Banking/finance: European banks remain a concern in this scenario because low/negative rates squeeze their margins for a long time, and weak growth means higher non-performing loans. We might see a need for banking consolidation or even state support for some weaker banks (like Italy’s or Germany’s smaller banks) if profitability is too low. But overall, not a meltdown, just zombie banking. Euro stability: In the worst case, investors might question the sustainability of some sovereign debts. For instance, if Italy’s economy stagnates and the ECB eventually tries to taper stimulus, bond spreads could widen dangerously. However, given lessons learned, the ECB would likely maintain support (via QE or even yield curve control for sovereign spreads) to prevent a Eurozone breakup scenario. So the euro area holds together but at the cost of ongoing central bank intervention. Currency: The euro likely weakens in a global stagnation scenario because the U.S. might still look relatively better or at least the Fed might have slightly more room than the ECB. Also, investors seeking yield might avoid euro assets if rates are negative. So EUR/USD might drop back near parity ($1.0–1.1). A weaker euro could help net exports a bit, but if global demand is weak, it’s not a panacea. UK: Though not explicitly asked, note the UK could similarly have a rough time – high debt, reliant on foreign financing, and stagflation potential. It might mirror Europe’s path or worse due to Brexit constraints. 
  • Asia: In a prolonged global slump, Asia is hit via trade and financial channels. China may struggle to meet even its lowered growth targets. If global demand is anaemic, China’s export machine sputters. Domestically, if property markets never quite recover, China could have Japan-like deflationary pressures (already in 2023 China had deflation fears). We could see Chinese growth sliding to ~3% or below by the late 2020s. That’s essentially stagnation for China, given its ambitions and still-developing status. China’s government might respond with massive stimulus (they have more fiscal space than the West arguably, and a controlled financial system). However, more debt-fueled stimulus could worsen their debt imbalances without restoring strong growth – a liquidity trap of its sort. There’s a chance that if Western demand is weak, China will pivot more aggressively to domestic consumption via wealth redistribution or social safety net improvements, but those take time. Japan likely falls back into near-zero inflation or deflation, vindicating pessimists that the recent uptick was temporary. BoJ might re-institute yield curve control at nearly 0% and become a permanent fixture in markets. Emerging Asian economies (like Southeast Asia, and India) would see growth curtailed – maybe growing at half their potential rate. For example, India might grow only ~3–4% instead of 6%, due to weak global investment and possibly its financial problems if interest rates globally are volatile. One glimmer: these economies have internal demand drivers and might use the opportunity of low commodity prices to implement reforms, but generally their convergence would slow. Global trade and dollar system: A slump with low inflation likely means global interest rates are low everywhere, and liquidity is abundant but not eagerly invested (classic pushing on a string). The Eurodollar system might balloon in size because central banks are providing lots of liquidity and investors park it in safe dollar assets – we saw that post-2008: a global savings glut intensified, keeping yields low. However, emerging markets might not benefit if risk aversion is high; they could see capital outflows and weaker currencies despite low U.S. yields (like the post-2013 environment for some). However, one difference: if the U.S. is at zero rates, the yield-seeking might return to emerging markets eventually (as happened mid-2010s when EMs got flows due to zero U.S. rates). But if those EMs have structural issues, capital might still shy away. Commodity exporters (like the Middle East, Russia, Africa, and Latin America) suffer in this scenario with persistently low commodity prices and demand. This could cause debt crises or political instability in some of those regions by 2026–27, which, while not the focus, could add to global risks (further reason for investors to be conservative). 


Bottom line (Medium-Term Slump): This scenario (~25% probability) essentially is a prolongation of recessionary conditions and a deflationary aftermath. It underscores the risk that if the economy’s fundamental engines (productivity, confidence) are not reignited, we could end up in a quasi-stagnant equilibrium – not free-fall, but grinding along the bottom. Key variables: by 2027, unemployment elevated, inflation below 1% (many developed economies flirting with deflation), policy rates ~0% in U.S./Europe (pushing limits of conventional policy), public debt higher (due to low growth, possibly >100% of GDP in U.S., ~120% EU avg, >300% of GDP in Japan), 10-year yields very low (~1-2%), equity markets not far above their troughs, housing markets down or flat, and global GDP growth maybe ~2% or less (half of pre-2020 norms). Historically, this mirrors Japan’s lost decades and also the post-GFC secular stagnation fears that were only alleviated by extraordinary stimulus (and arguably by the external shock of pandemic stimulus which reset things). It’s essentially the scenario where the arguments about wealth vs productivity come to roost: since productivity didn’t catch up to wealth, wealth falls to meet productivity, and that process weighs on the economy for years. The risk is that the longer the slump, the more permanent damage (hysteresis) – e.g., workers drop out, investment forgone – making it even harder to escape. 

Alternative 2 (≈20% probability) – “High-Inflation Regime (Stagflation to Hard Landing)” 

Overview: In this medium-term alternative, the stagflationary pressures from the short term persist and even intensify, leading to a prolonged period of high inflation and subpar growth. Essentially, the global economy of 2025–2027 starts to resemble the late 1970s: inflation that is entrenched above target (say in the 4–6% range) and growth that is erratic and generally weak, punctuated by policy-induced slowdowns. Central banks, having initially hesitated to crush the inflation due to growth concerns (as in the short-term stagflation scenario), eventually realised that without a significant monetary tightening, inflation would not revert to 2%. Thus, sometime in this horizon, they may be forced into a “Volcker moment” – i.e. an aggressive tightening that likely triggers a recession (a hard landing) but is deemed necessary to break inflation’s back. The timing could be towards 2026 or 2027 if inflation hasn’t improved. Alternatively, policymakers might still delay, resulting in inflation remaining high through 2027 (a “higher for longer” with no crash yet, but also no resolution). In both variants, inflation expectations risk de-anchoring among the public and investors, which in turn could lead to a vicious cycle of rising wages, prices, and interest rates. Meanwhile, fiscal dynamics deteriorate under high nominal yields, raising debt sustainability issues. This scenario encompasses both the possibility of persistent stagflation and the eventual likelihood of a sharper hard landing later if central banks capitulate to the need for drastic action. It is somewhat the opposite of Alternative 1: here the economy doesn’t slow enough on its own, requiring a forced slowdown later. 

  • United States: Suppose through 2025–26 the Fed manages only to nibble at inflation, not break it. By 2027, U.S. inflation could still be running around 4% or higher. Perhaps it oscillates – e.g., cools to 3% one year, then a new shock (oil, geopolitical conflict or fiscal expansion) pushes it back to 5%. The average remains well above 2%. Inflation expectations among consumers and businesses drift upward; 5-year forward inflation expectations might rise from ~2% to, say, 3%+, a worrying sign. The Fed in earlier years might have stuck to a policy rate of around 4-5%, which proved insufficient to tame inflation. By 2026, seeing no alternative, the Fed decides to forcefully hike into restrictive territory (just as Volcker did starting in 1979 and leading into the 1981–82 recession). We could envision the Fed raising rates to, say, 6–7% (which in real terms might be only ~2% if inflation is 4-5%). This finally causes a more severe tightening of financial conditions. The bond market likely anticipates this eventual pivot – we might see long-term yields rising steadily through 2025 and 2026. For instance, the 10-year Treasury yield could climb into the 5–6% range by 2026, as markets demand higher compensation for inflation and as the Fed’s own long-run neutral rate estimate perhaps rises. Such levels would be the highest since the early 2000s and would materially raise borrowing costs economy-wide. Economic growth: Under the weight of these rates, the economy can’t sustain growth. If a recession hasn’t occurred yet, one becomes highly likely by 2026–27. This would be a hard landing orchestrated by late policy action. It could be quite severe because by now debt levels are higher (households and businesses have been operating with high inflation but also likely accumulating debt, thinking nominal growth will bail them out). When high rates hit, heavily indebted entities suffer (some defaults, bankruptcies – maybe a wave of corporate failures similar to the early 80s when many industrial firms and Latin American countries defaulted under high U.S. rates). We might see unemployment shoot up to, say, 7–8% in this late hard landing – a deeper shock than the Alt 1 recession which was milder. In effect, this scenario compresses the pain that was avoided earlier into a later period, potentially making it sharper (the “pay later” scenario). Fiscal impact: The U.S. fiscal situation becomes challenging. With 10y yields of ~5-6%, the government’s interest expenses mount (a lot of debt rolls over every year). If inflation is high, it boosts nominal GDP (which could help debt/GDP in the short run) but also boosts interest costs and possibly triggers higher entitlement spending (indexed benefits). If a hard landing then occurs, deficits blow out (as in the early 80s with Reagan deficits + high rates). By 2027, the U.S. debt-to-GDP could be significantly higher than today, and markets may start questioning long-run debt sustainability – potentially pressuring the Fed with concerns of fiscal dominance. Consumer and business adaptation: During the persistent inflation phase, consumers and firms change behaviour – cost-of-living adjustments (COLA) in wages become common, contracts get indexed to inflation, and businesses price more frequently. This adaptation can entrench inflation (like the 70s). Ultimately, the late hard landing is needed to break that cycle – e.g., causing a spike in unemployment that finally dampens wage demands, akin to 1982 when the U.S. jobless rate hit 10%. Asset markets: In the run-up, asset prices might not collapse initially because high inflation often props up nominal revenues (companies have higher sales in nominal terms) and erodes real debt (which can be good for equity until interest rates catch up). But as soon as the market senses the Fed will have to go nuclear, equities re-rate downward heavily. Possibly a big market crash occurs in mid-2026 when the Fed’s stance shifts aggressively. The S&P could drop 30%+ in that event. Housing in high inflation might see nominal prices hold or even rise (people buy real assets as an inflation hedge), but with mortgage rates eventually soaring to double digits (if 10y is 5-6%, 30y mortgage could be ~8-9% or more), housing affordability collapses and a housing bust follows. Home prices could fall significantly in real terms, though perhaps not as visibly in nominal terms if inflation remains high. For example, home prices might plateau nominally but inflation-adjusted they’re down 20%. Construction slumps due to expensive financing. 
  • Europe: A high inflation regime in Europe could be particularly tricky. Europe’s inflation in this scenario likely remains elevated as well – perhaps not quite as high as the U.S. if demand is weaker, but sticky enough (say Eurozone inflation ~3–4% through 2025–26). The ECB, initially slower to tighten aggressively (due to fears of hurting weaker economies), eventually realises inflation expectations are drifting up. It might then tighten in late 2025 or 2026 even at the cost of a serious recession in Southern Europe. We could see the ECB policy rate back up to its peak of ~4% or higher, and possibly the need to do it despite governments’ objections. The result might be a renewed Eurozone crisis environment: high rates push Italy or others to the brink of debt unsustainability. Unlike 2012, however, now inflation is high, so the ECB is in a bind – it wants to tighten to quell inflation but that undermines fiscal stability. This is the dreaded fiscal dominance scenario: the central bank’s inflation fight is constrained by government debt concerns. If the ECB caves to fiscal pressure and monetises debt (keeps buying bonds, tolerating higher inflation), the euro could lose credibility (possibly a scenario where the euro weakens sharply and risk premia rises). If instead, the ECB sticks to fighting inflation, we might see a restructuring or bailouts needed for some sovereigns or a massive EU-level intervention to share the burden. Either path is fraught. Growth: Europe likely ends up in recession by mid-decade either way but with inflation still relatively high (stagflation turning into a possibly deeper stagflation or eventual disinflation via collapse). Stagflation persistence: Possibly the worst for Europe is stagflation without resolution – reminiscent of the UK in the 1970s (which had high inflation and weak growth until monetarist policies in the 80s). Unemployment would rise, but if wages chase prices, you get unemployment and inflation together (the infamous misery index is very high). Political climate: High inflation erodes real incomes significantly. In Europe, this could trigger strong social unrest (e.g., mass strikes, as seen when inflation spiked in 2023, but more widespread). Pressure on governments to shield citizens could result in more fiscal spending (which further fuels inflation – a vicious circle). 
  • Asia: In a globally inflationary scenario, Asia too would face higher inflation than in the base case. Emerging Asia could see inflation in mid-to-high single digits, forcing their central banks to hike and possibly causing growth to fall short. India might have persistent 6%+ inflation, RBI keeps policy tight, hence growth may only be ~4-5% instead of 6-7%. China interestingly might export inflation through supply chains (charging higher prices for exports as its costs rise), but China’s demand might not be as overheated. If China maintains a relatively easier policy to support growth while the West is in stagflation, its currency (RMB) might depreciate, causing some inflation. If commodities are high (likely, if inflation is partly driven by energy/food), China’s import bill surges, adding strain. They might resort to price controls or strategic stockpile usage. Japan, after finally seeing inflation >2%, might ironically have the opposite problem of needing to contain inflation – a new challenge after decades of trying to raise it. If the yen stays weak in a high global inflation environment, imported inflation could push Japan to tighten policy (e.g. end YCC, raise rates) for the first time in forever, which could unsettle Japanese markets given huge public debt. So even Japan could face a kind of reckoning. Global trade: A high-inflation regime often leads to more protectionism as countries try to combat domestic price pressures (export bans, tariffs etc.). We saw hints of this in 2022 (food export bans, etc.). If that continues, globalisation could retreat further, reducing efficiency and potentially keeping inflation pressures simmering. 

Bottom line (Medium-Term High Inflation): In this scenario (~20% probability), the world is essentially caught in a stagflation trap that either doesn’t resolve by 2027 (if policymakers remain cautious) or ends in a sharp crisis when they finally act. Key features by 2027: inflation well above target (perhaps halved from 2022 peak but stuck in the 3–5% range in advanced economies, higher in some EM), interest rates high (policy rates possibly 6-7% US, 4%+ ECB at peak, then maybe falling if a late recession hits), growth performance poor (cumulative growth over 2024–27 near zero in many regions), unemployment eventually high (if the reckoning recession happens; if not, unemployment might be moderate but with many underemployed due to cost pressures), debt costs surging (sovereign and corporate defaults could rise), and market volatility extreme. One might see multiple mini-crises: perhaps an EM debt crisis (like 1980s LatAm), a housing market collapse in overly leveraged markets, or a currency crisis in a weak-link country. Comparatively, it’s like an extended late-1970s into early-80s scenario on fast-forward. A critical difference vs 2008: here the problem is not lack of demand but too much nominal demand relative to supply, so the remedy is very different (tightening vs stimulating). The risk is that in trying to avoid short-term pain, authorities amplify long-term pain – a lesson from history.

(See Table 2 for a comparative overview of medium-term scenario projections for key indicators.)

Long-Term Scenarios (4+ Years Out) 

Horizon: ~4 years (to 2029 and beyond). At this horizon, the short- and medium-term dynamics culminate in more structural outcomes for the global economy. We consider where the U.S., Europe, and Asia might stand by around 2029 under a Base Case and alternatives, incorporating the lasting impacts of the trends discussed: how much of the 2020s inflation shock is truly past, what the growth potential is, and whether global financial conditions stabilise or not. Historical reference points include the post-1970s period (when either high inflation was vanquished leading to the ’80s boom, or in some countries inflation persisted into high-debt crises), the post-2008 decade (secular stagnation vs slow healing), and Japan’s trajectory. We also examine how interconnected global risks (climate events, geopolitical shifts) might intersect with these scenarios, even though the focus remains macro-financial. 

Base Case (≈50% probability) – “Stable Growth and Low Inflation (New Normal)” 

Overview: In the long-term base case, by 2029 the global economy has settled into a new equilibrium of relatively stable growth and low inflation – essentially a return to macro stability after the turbulent 2020–2024 period, but not an exact return to pre-2020 conditions. The key difference in this new normal is that policymakers and economic agents have adapted lessons from the tumultuous 2020s: central banks are vigilant but also humble (using new tools to manage both inflation and financial stability), fiscal authorities are more mindful of supply-side policies (e.g., encouraging investment, removing bottlenecks), and the private sector has adjusted to more normal interest rate levels (no longer expecting near-zero rates or asset values doubling every few years). Productivity growth has picked up somewhat due to technological adoption (AI, automation, energy transition investments), which helps sustain growth without reigniting inflation. Asset prices are much more closely aligned with fundamentals – the excess froth is gone, but steady gains occur in line with earnings and income. The financial system is robust, with banks well-capitalised and shadow banking monitored, reducing crisis risk. Global cooperation on certain fronts (like liquidity provision via central bank swaps, or a shared understanding of inflation targets) remains intact, contributing to stability. There may still be debt overhangs, but high nominal growth and low real rates in the mid-decade likely eroded some debt ratios, giving breathing room. This scenario is akin to a “soft landing + productivity renaissance” outcome, sometimes dubbed “Goldilocks” – not too hot, not too cold, and surprisingly resilient. It’s essentially the best realistic outcome given starting conditions, though not without challenges (growth is moderate, not spectacular). 

  • United States: By 2029, the U.S. economy in this scenario is in its expansion phase, albeit a moderate one. Real GDP likely surpassed its pre-pandemic trend line or at least converged back to it. Average growth in the late 2020s might be ~2.0–2.5% annually, higher than the anaemic 1.5% of the late 2010s, partly due to better productivity. Inflation is firmly at ~2% or slightly below, and the Fed is credibly hitting its target (perhaps undershooting occasionally but within comfort). The Fed’s policy rate is around a new neutral of ~2.5–3%, and monetary policy operates mostly through normal channels – no constant emergency measures. The Fed likely has a slightly larger balance sheet than in 2019 but has mostly normalized it relative to GDP. The yield curve in 2029 is gently upward sloping, with 10-year Treasuries around 3–3.5%, reflecting stable inflation expectations and a modest term premium as investors feel confident about long-term stability. One change might be a lower r-star (neutral real rate) than historically – if demographics and global savings glut remain factors – but likely around 0.5–1% real (so 2.5–3% nominal at 2% inflation). Fiscal: The U.S. fiscal health is manageable. Perhaps debt/GDP is slightly higher (maybe ~110-115%), but with low interest rates, interest payments are only a moderate share of GDP. Some fiscal consolidation might have occurred via growth and inflation rather than austerity. Policy priorities may have shifted to long-term issues (like entitlement reforms or climate investments) rather than emergency stimulus. Labour market and productivity: Unemployment might be low (~4%) with labour force participation stabilised or even improved (older workers possibly staying on due to remote work options, etc.). The workforce has adapted: automation handles more mundane tasks, and workers have upskilled (partly a response to labour shortages earlier). Productivity growth might be trending at 1.5–2% annually, as mentioned. If an AI revolution truly took off, we could even see higher, but the base assumption is a moderate improvement. This helps keep unit labour costs in check, which is one reason inflation stays low even as wages rise ~3-4% (balanced by 2% productivity, that’s a 1-2% unit cost increase, consistent with 2% inflation). Income and inequality: Possibly, policy and market forces in this scenario addressed some inequality – e.g., wage gains for lower-income workers (which were strong in the late 2010s) continued, and asset price hyperinflation (which mainly benefitted the rich) did not resume. So the fruits of growth are a bit more widely shared, which supports a sustainable consumer demand base. Housing and assets: By the late 2020s, housing has found a new equilibrium. Real home prices might not be much higher than 2020s, due to the corrections and new supply, but housing is more affordable relative to income. The focus might shift to the quality of housing (energy-efficient homes, etc.) rather than speculative gains. Equity markets in 2029 likely reflect roughly a decade of earnings growth since 2019 with some bumps. The S&P 500 level could be meaningfully higher than 2023, but the valuation metrics look reasonable (P/E maybe ~17-18). Investors have more realistic return expectations (no longer expecting 20%/yr). This environment fosters higher long-term investment, as capital is allocated to productive uses rather than chasing the next asset bubble. Financial sector: The banking system has fully absorbed any shocks from the early decade, and thanks to strong regulation, remains stable. Perhaps big tech or fintech players have integrated into finance more but without systemic instability. Shadow banking (money market funds, etc.) is better supervised after lessons of 2020’s run; institutions have buffers. Consumer and business sentiment: Likely optimistic. If we draw a parallel, it could be like the late 1990s (but without the tech bubble): unemployment low, inflation low, new technologies emerging and boosting confidence. The crucial difference is demographics (ageing population) might cap how exuberant growth gets – we might not see 4% GDP growth, but a steady 2-3% can still feel good if it’s stable. 
  • Europe: By 2029 in the base scenario, Europe also has stabilised. Euro Area growth might be modest ~1.5% trend, reflecting its slower labour force growth, but importantly it’s stable and not crisis-prone. Inflation is at the ECB’s 2% target and perhaps the ECB even formally moved to a symmetric target (as it did in reality, saying 2% symmetric). The ECB policy rate could be around 1.5–2%, slightly lower than the Fed’s due to lower r*. The Euro Area might have advanced some structural reforms: e.g., capital markets union progress, and some fiscal integration (maybe a permanent EU investment fund like NextGenEU extended), which improve resilience. Public debt in key countries like Italy might have declined relative to GDP since the mid-decade because growth and mild inflation helped (plus perhaps some mutualisation or ECB holdings easing pressure). By ensuring inflation didn’t overshoot, the ECB avoided the worst of the high-debt/high-rate trap. Europe’s supply side: The energy transition accelerated: by 2029 a significant share of energy is renewable, buffering Europe from oil/gas shocks. This both improves trade balance and reduces inflation volatility. Also, digital adoption might have improved productivity in services, raising Europe’s potential growth a bit. Labour markets: remain tight but in a good way – unemployment perhaps ~6% Eurozone average, which is quite low historically. Wage growth ~2-3%, productivity ~1%, so unit labour cost ~1-2%, consistent with 2% inflation, a similar dynamic as the U.S. The EU possibly benefitted from some relocation of supply chains (e.g., more EV battery factories in Europe, etc.) which created jobs. UK: Outside the EU, presumably the UK joins this stable pattern albeit with slightly higher inflation (the UK tends to run a bit hotter inflation historically) but generally convergent policies (BoE also around 2% target, rate 2-3%). Financial stability: European banks, if they weathered earlier stress, 2029 might be on firmer ground. Possibly consolidation happened (there might be fewer banks but stronger ones). The Capital Markets Union could mean more equity financing relative to debt, reducing bank burdens. Inter-country cohesion: With stability, EU cohesion likely improves. Countries are less likely to elect extremist anti-EU governments when the economy is fine – this scenario likely sees moderate governments cooperating (some parallels to the mid-2000s when Europe was relatively politically stable pre-GFC). That reduces tail risks like the euro breakup. Euro as a currency: If everything is stable, the euro could remain around a fair value ($1.15), maybe even slightly stronger if the dollar’s exorbitant privilege erodes a bit. But likely within a manageable range, meaning no big imbalances from FX. Europe’s main challenge in the base scenario is dealing with the ageing population – by 2029, a lot of baby boomers in the EU will be retired. But if productivity is up and immigration has been supplemented (maybe Europe accepted more immigrants e.g. from Africa or Ukraine to bolster the workforce), they can offset that somewhat. 
  • Asia: In the base long-term case, Asia continues to be a growth engine. China likely has settled to a lower but stable growth path, maybe ~4% as a new normal (given ageing and high base, which is still decent for an economy of that size). The big question is whether China made progress in rebalancing: in a positive scenario, by the late 2020s, China’s consumption share of GDP was higher, debt growth was controlled, and they avoided a financial crisis. Perhaps their property sector underwent a managed shrinkage (house prices in China may have stagnated for years, making housing more affordable for the young without a crash – a soft landing in property). China’s inflation likely remains modest ~2-3% (they historically manage inflation tightly). The yuan might be more international by 2029, but the USD is likely still dominant – however, China might invoice more trade in CNY, sign more swap lines with other countries, etc. India and other South/Southeast Asian economies by 2029 could be in a sweet spot if global stability holds: India could sustain ~6% growth, benefiting from demographics and reforms, becoming a larger part of global demand. ASEAN countries average ~4-5%. Japan in a base-case long run might have finally escaped deflation’s shadow: could be running at ~1% growth, and 1-2% inflation, which for Japan is quite good (with population shrinking ~0.5%/yr, 1% GDP implies ~1.5% productivity growth – achievable with tech). The Bank of Japan might have normalized policy (no negative rates, maybe a policy rate of ~1% and 10y yield of ~1.5%), still low but not zero. Globally, the pattern is again synchronised stability – something like the early 2000s (2004-06) or mid-90s, but hopefully without a looming crisis building underneath. Trade: With lessons from the pandemic, supply chains are more diversified, but globalization hasn’t fully reversed; instead it pivoted – perhaps less focus on China, and more on multi-hub (Vietnam, India, Mexico, etc. all integrated). This diversification improved resilience so a single shock (like one country lockdown) is less disruptive, contributing to stability. Global current account imbalances might be narrower: U.S. energy production etc. improved its trade balance, China’s rebalancing shrank its surplus, etc., meaning less chance of major currency crises or trade wars. Technological collaboration: Possibly in this optimistic case, countries cooperate on climate tech, global standards, etc., which could raise global productivity a bit. Climate impact: One cannot ignore that by the late-2020s, climate change effects (weather disasters) could be more frequent, but in a stable-growth scenario, countries can invest in resilience without derailing economies. For instance, infrastructure spending to adapt to climate is expansionary and done in a planned way, rather than reactive humanitarian spending after disasters. 


Bottom line (Long-Term Base): By 2029, the world looks relatively healthy economically: moderate growth, low inflation, and learned lessons keep financial excesses in check. The notion that asset prices can diverge wildly from productivity has been discredited by the events of the early 2020s, and both policymakers and investors behave more prudently. Central banks remain credible (the Fed and ECB succeeded in their mandates without major misses – quite unlike the 1970s). As a result, long-term inflation expectations are anchored, which itself is a self-fulfilling stabiliser. Public and private balance sheets are not perfect but better aligned (e.g. perhaps households have less debt relative to income than in 2019 after deleveraging in the mid-2020s, and governments, while more indebted, face low rates making it manageable). This scenario essentially represents a return to something like “the Great Moderation 2.0”, albeit with some structural differences (perhaps slightly higher neutral rates than the 2010s, more digitalisation, and more focus on climate and inclusive growth). Probability ~50% is assigned – it’s a hopeful outcome but plausible if correct actions are taken. 

Alternative 1 (≈30% probability) – “Global Deleveraging and Low Growth (Japanification)” 

Overview: In this adverse long-term scenario, the world in 2029 is mired in the consequences of the balance sheet reset and slump that followed the early-2020s boom. It resembles a “Japanification” of the global economy: ultra-low interest rates, low or negative inflation, and chronically weak growth as both private and public sectors carry heavy debt burdens and focus on deleveraging. The term “Japanification” refers to what Japan experienced after its 1980s bubble burst – decades of very low growth/deflation despite zero interest rates, due to an overhang of debt and reluctance to spend or invest. In this scenario, one can imagine that the Alternative 1 medium-term slump continued or even worsened. Perhaps repeated fiscal austerity or policy missteps prevented a robust recovery, and any growth that did occur was absorbed by debt repayment rather than new demand. By 2029, inflation expectations might have fallen to near zero or even become negative (people expect falling prices), which is dangerous as it raises real debt burdens further – a deflationary trap. The global economy essentially operates far below capacity, and unemployment, while maybe not explosively high (some dropped out of the labour force, others took pay cuts), is above full employment levels. Interest rates have been at the zero bound so long that central banks have lost some influence, and unconventional tools have diminishing returns. There’s a sense of stagnation and resignation – it’s not an acute crisis (those happened earlier, perhaps some sovereign restructurings or banking rescues happened mid-decade), but a slow grind. 

  • United States: In this scenario, the U.S. by 2029 might have a real GDP growth trend of only ~1% or less, with several mini-recessions or flat years along the way (like 2026 and 2028 are flat, maybe 2027 slightly up, etc.). The level of output could be significantly below the pre-2020 trend line (lost output not recovered). Inflation is around 0% to 1%, and the Fed consistently undershoots its 2% target – effectively, the U.S. is in a deflationary environment. The Fed funds rate has been at the zero lower bound for years now, and the Fed might even have tried some form of negative rates or enhanced forward guidance, but politically that is tough in the U.S. (so likely stuck at zero). The Fed’s balance sheet could be enormous because they attempted more QE – possibly owning not just Treasuries and MBS but maybe corporate bonds or other assets if legally enabled – basically acting as a supporter of last resort. Yet these efforts only managed to stabilise financial markets (keeping yields low) but didn’t spur strong growth due to a liquidity trap – banks have excess reserves but few willing borrowers. Bond yields: The 10-year yield might be ~1% or even lower. Perhaps yield curve control was implemented at some point to cap yields (like BoJ style) if debt got high. Investors expecting low inflation and periodic Fed buying are content with 1% yields as there’s little else (stocks aren’t giving much better, etc.). Debt levels: ironically, public debt might be extremely high as a per cent of GDP (because denominator growth/inflation is so low). The U.S. could be at, say, 150% debt/GDP by 2029 after years of large deficits from stimulus and low growth. However, the low interest rates mean that the government can finance it at near zero cost – similar to Japan’s situation where debt is >250% of GDP but mostly internally held at low rates. There might be more open discussion of Modern Monetary Theory or debt monetization since traditional thinking hasn’t solved deflation, but likely confidence in such measures is low. Consumer behaviour: Households, after the asset bust, remain conservative – high saving, low appetite for credit. Younger generations might invest less in stock markets (burned by earlier volatility) and more in safe assets or even cash, prolonging the low-rate environment (paradox of thrift economy-wide). Assets: Equity markets might be range-bound for the decade, delivering poor returns. The S&P 500 in 2029 could be around similar levels as the mid-2020s, just oscillating. Some high-dividend, stable stocks might do okay (like utilities – similar to how in Japan, certain defensive stocks did alright, but the overall market stagnated). Housing: Real estate might similarly stagnate in price (nominal and real). With low rates, one might think housing would boom, but if banks are cautious and population growth is low, housing just becomes a stable utility-like asset. Homeownership might rise because prices are low and credit is cheap – ironically improving affordability – but housing is not an engine of growth, just a place to live. Banking: Banks probably consolidate and shrink in influence, as in Japan. Some may turn essentially into utilities holding government bonds and taking deposits (because lending opportunities are scarce). Financial innovation slows in a deflationary climate – it’s hard to have a vibrant FinTech scene if there’s little credit demand or return. Productivity: Possibly also low, because investment in new tech is meager (who wants to invest in expansion in a stagnating economy?). This could become a vicious cycle: low productivity -> low growth -> low demand -> low investment -> etc. However, one nuance: sometimes pressure can spur efficiency gains (as companies struggle, they automate to cut costs). But if demand is lacking, even cost-cutting improvements might just lead to downsizing rather than output expansion. Psychology: The public might come to expect stagnation as the norm. This happened in Japan – deflationary mindset: people hold off buying big items because they think prices might fall further, which further suppresses demand. Breaking out of this mindset is very difficult (took Japan decades and they still haven’t fully). The U.S. historically is more dynamic, but even it could fall into this trap under certain conditions (especially if politics are dysfunctional and cannot deliver effective stimulus). 
  • Europe: Europe could fare even worse under global japanification. The Eurozone was already at risk of this in the 2010s. By 2029 in this scenario, Euro Area growth might be ~0–1% trend and inflation around 0% (very likely some countries in deflation). The ECB would have reinstated negative interest rates (say deposit rate –0.5% or –1%) and resumed massive QE (maybe owning a large share of members’ sovereign bonds effectively). The ECB might have to more explicitly support governments (blurring the monetary-fiscal line) because some like Italy might have had to restructure or be constantly financed by ECB to avoid default in a deflationary spiral. Possibly a scenario where the EU changed rules to allow perpetual low-cost refinancing or even some debt mutualisation just to keep the union intact in the face of stagnation – e.g., a portion of national debts converted to Eurobonds held by ECB indefinitely (a stealth monetisation). This might keep the Eurozone together but at the cost of extremely slow growth and constant policy intervention. Unemployment in Europe could remain high (8-10%), but interestingly if the population shrinks maybe not as visibly high – the labor force may contract as people emigrate or drop out. Some younger Europeans might leave for better opportunities elsewhere (like how some Japanese moved abroad for opportunities). Social fabric: High structural unemployment and no growth can breed extreme politics, but by 2029 maybe populations become apathetic instead – in Japan people adapted to low growth by focusing on stability and social harmony. Europe is more diverse, so stagnation might cause divergent national politics (some begging for more stimulus, others resisting transfers). There is a risk that such a scenario could put a strain on the EU – rich countries tired of financing poorer ones with nothing to show, poorer ones in perpetual slump resent rich ones. But I assume in base they manage to hold it together with compromises. Possibly the euro stays weak (maybe below parity) because no one expects much from Europe – though if the U.S. is also low yield, capital might still stick with Europe due to inertia. Assets: European equities are probably as flat as the U.S. or worse. Japanese equities lost like 75% from 1989 to 2009. Europe didn’t have as extreme a bubble, but still, say Euro Stoxx could be lower in 2029 than in 2019. Real estate in Europe might hold value better because of limited supply and low rates, but demand is low, so maybe mild deflation in housing too. Banks: European banks struggle – many become zombie banks supported by ECB funding. Possibly some big banks nationalised or merged. The financial landscape might shift more to government-controlled or few big players with implicit state backing. 
  • Asia: In a japanification scenario, ironically Japan itself would just continue what it’s had – so it’s not a shock for them, just disappointing that they never got a breakout. They’d still be around 0–1% growth, struggling with ageing, and maybe even worse if global demand is weak. China is interesting: a prolonged global slump could be disastrous for China’s ambitions. By 2029, China could be stuck in the “middle-income trap” – growth has fallen to ~2% or less, which is near stagnation given their aspirations. Possibly deflation there too if their debt bubble unwinds. If the world is deflationary, China’s exports face weak demand, and its enormous domestic debts (especially local governments, and state enterprises) become harder to service with low inflation. It could face a lost decade of its own – not achieving developed status by 2030 as hoped. Social stability might be tested if urban unemployment rises due to a lack of growth drivers (and they have aged as well by then). That said, China’s government may fight stagnation with periodic large spending, which might prevent deeper recessions but also raise debt more – essentially following Japans post-90 path of many fiscal stimulus packages to prop up a low-growth economy. Emerging Asia: many would suffer from permanent lower demand for exports, and low commodity prices if deflationary (hurting Indonesia, and Malaysia). They might rely on small domestic markets, so possibly stuck with low growth as well. On the bright side, very low global rates can allow them to borrow cheaply if they have market access, but if growth prospects are poor, investors may not be keen anyway. Global trade/investment flows: likely shrink as a per cent of GDP (as happened after 2008 for a while). Protectionism might increase as countries try to grab a bigger slice of a stagnant pie for themselves (though if everyone’s stagnant, there might be less conflict because nobody has inflation to blame on trade – but they might blame trade for low jobs). Geopolitics: A stagnating world could either reduce conflicts (everyone focusing inward on the economy, fewer resources for the military) or exacerbate them (scapegoating foreigners). Historically, prolonged economic malaise can lead to political instability and conflict (e.g., the 1930s). We might see more isolationism, weaker global institutions, and maybe regional fragmentation as rich areas pull away (e.g., could the Eurozone see core vs periphery break? Possibly, but let’s assume not in this scenario, just because that would be an even deeper crisis). Instead, likely global leadership remains gridlocked, managing crises at home more than cooperating. 


Bottom line (Long-Term Slump/Japanification): The world of 2029 here is one of missed opportunities and lingering malaise. It has echoes of the 1930s Depression (without the sharp initial contraction) or 1990s Japan globally. Everything feels like it’s in low gear: inflation ~0%, interest rates ~0%, growth ~0-1% in advanced economies, slightly more in EMs but well below potential, debt high, and policy ineffective (central banks practically pushing on a string, fiscal policy hampered by high debt and political discord). The positive is that outright crises might be largely avoided after the early adjustments – because everyone is so conservative, you don’t get new bubbles or hyperinflation or such. But the cost is a generation of stagnation. Probability ~30% in our assessment, because avoiding it would require effective demand management earlier – if that fails, this could ensue. 

Alternative 2 (≈20% probability) – “High Inflation and Debt Distress (1970s Redux or Worse)” 

Overview: In this worst-case long-term scenario, the efforts to control the inflation of the 2020s fail, and the world enters the late 2020s with inflation not only unresolved but potentially accelerating. This is essential if the medium-term high inflation/stagflation scenario continues. By 2029, we could have a situation analogous to the late 1970s/early 1980s, or perhaps even a more systemic global crisis triggered by high inflation and interest rates. Key characteristics: inflation expectations unanchored (people don’t trust central banks to maintain price stability), wage-price spirals in multiple countries, central banks either behind the curve or causing severe recessions to catch up, and government debt under strain as interest costs explode. This scenario might culminate in sovereign debt crises or currency crises in some economies. For example, some highly indebted countries might default or require IMF rescues (think 1980s Latin America or even Italy risk). The global financial system could be stressed by both high default rates (as high rates make loans unpayable) and high volatility (as investors flee currencies or bond markets that they lose confidence in). Essentially, this is a return to a pre-1990s world of macro volatility: big recessions, big inflations alternating. The extreme version could even see hyperinflation in some mismanaged economies, though major economies likely avoid that. But even moderately high inflation (e.g. sustained 10%+ in some countries) is disastrous enough for long-term planning and capital formation. 

  • United States: If stagflation persisted, by the late 2020s the U.S. could see an episode of very high inflation – say inflation runs >5% year after year, possibly reaching double digits if there’s an oil shock or other trigger. If the Fed still hesitated, things could get out of hand. Alternatively, suppose the Fed does try to crack down belatedly (like Volcker did around 1979–80). In doing so, it might need to raise rates extremely high (Volcker took Fed funds to ~20% in 1981). Under today’s conditions, Fed funds anywhere near that would cause carnage given how much debt is in the system. One can imagine by 2027 the Fed has hiked to say 8-10% trying to stem 7% inflation and still struggling. This yields a severe recession around 2027–28 (maybe akin to 1981-82 which was very deep). Unemployment could spike to, say, 10% or more under that shock (like the early 80s). Only after that, by 2029, could inflation finally start trending down – but at an enormous cost. Bond market: Even before that, in the mid-2020s, bond investors would have demanded much higher yields to hold treasuries if they expected future inflation eroding value. The 10-year yield could have soared to, say, 8% or more at some point (especially if foreign investors lost appetite and the Fed wasn’t buying due to the tightening stance). The U.S. government’s interest costs would balloon. Fiscal crisis risk: The U.S. has the advantage of issuing debt in its currency (and reserve currency), so a classic default is unlikely. But it could face a form of fiscal dominance where the Fed might be pressured to tolerate higher inflation to erode the real debt or to avoid making interest costs unsustainable. If the Fed yields to that (i.e., effectively monetises debt), that’s a path to continued high inflation (like some Latin American countries in past). If it doesn’t (i.e., it slams inflation down at the cost of output), debt/GDP might shoot up due to recession and high interest, forcing either drastic austerity or eventually inflation anyway – a lose-lose. Possibly by 2029, the U.S. might be forced into fiscal measures like significant spending cuts or tax hikes (like the early 80s did see some belt-tightening under Reagan after initial deficits). That could help long run, but the short run, combined with tight money, is extremely painful. Consumer impact: the average American suffers in this scenario from both high cost of living and job insecurity. Real incomes likely fall over several years (the 1970s saw falling real wages; could repeat). The inequality might shift: debtors benefit (inflation erodes their debts), and savers lose (unless they are in inflation hedges like property or TIPS). The social contract could fray: you might see more labour militancy (unions striking for higher pay to catch up with inflation – a hallmark of the 1970s). Currency: The U.S. dollar could go either way – if the Fed is behind the curve, the dollar weakens as investors seek currencies of countries with better policies (perhaps the dollar loses value to gold or a stable currency like maybe the euro if the ECB is doing better, or more likely to hard assets and non-fiat like gold/crypto if trust in fiat fades). If the Fed then overtightens, the dollar might spike massively (like it did in the early 80s, hitting record highs, and causing global issues). So potentially large FX volatility. Possibly a scenario of global currency misalignments and crises – e.g., some emerging currencies pegged to the dollar might break (like the 1980s debt crisis when the U.S. rate spike crushed many EM pegs). 
  • Europe: If the U.S. sneezes, Europe catches a cold – in a high inflation scenario, Europe too probably has high inflation, given energy vulnerabilities and all. If the ECB is also delayed, it might face similar or worse inflation because of the supply side (like in the 1970s, Europe had even worse stagflation due to higher energy dependence). Suppose Eurozone inflation e.g. 5-6% persistent. The ECB in the late 2020s would either live with it (eroding the euro’s credibility) or fight it with hikes that some economies cannot withstand. The risk of a Eurozone breakup would loom larger here – e.g., Italy with high debt could not handle 8% rates without restructuring. Maybe in this scenario, a country like Italy or Spain could default or leave the euro rather than endure depression-level austerity (extreme case, but probabilities rise under such stress). Or Germany might baulk at more bailouts if inflation is hurting their savers badly. Sovereign debt crises in the Eurozone could happen by the late 2020s: one or more countries needing rescue. The EU/IMF might do bailouts (like Greece in 2010, but larger scale), which would be very divisive. The euro might survive but with some scars (maybe joint debt issuance finally forced through to save the day, but causing political resentment). The UK similarly could have sterling crises if the policy is mismanaged (the UK historically had several in the 60s/70s). Already in 2022, a hint of that showed (bond market revolt). In this scenario, by the late 2020s UK might need IMF help or emergency rate hikes to save the pound if markets lose faith (like the 1976 sterling crisis). Banks and financial markets: High inflation & rates ravage fixed-income assets, so banks and insurers holding bonds incur huge losses (as in 2022, but magnified). Some might become insolvent, requiring government intervention. This scenario could see more financial institution failures – similar to the Savings & Loan crisis in the U.S. in the 80s or bank failures in some countries. Non-financial firms also default more under high rates (junk bond defaults surge). Possibly a global financial crisis triggered by a combination of inflation and tightening – but arguably central banks in this scenario prioritised the inflation fight even if things break (like Volcker said, its job to stick to its mission). So if something breaks (banking crisis), they face a conundrum: loosen to save banks (fueling inflation) or stay tight to quell inflation (letting banks fail)? Hard choices – maybe they do target bailouts but maintain a tight stance (like the Fed did lend to Continental Illinois in 1984 but kept policy tight). 
  • Emerging markets and Asia: A high inflation global scenario likely wreaks havoc in many emerging markets. Historically, U.S. high rates in the early 80s led to the Latin American debt crisis – countries like Mexico, and Brazil defaulted on external debt. Something similar could happen: many developing countries borrowed a lot in the low-rate 2010s and especially during the pandemic. If by the late 2020s global rates are high, we’d likely see a wave of EM sovereign defaults or restructurings (some already on edge like Zambia, and Sri Lanka, might be joined by bigger ones like maybe Turkey, Egypt, or even large ones if badly managed). The IMF would be busy with rescue programs. Asia’s emerging markets often handle inflation better (many are used to it, and some benefit as commodity exporters), but high U.S. rates could cause capital outflows, currency crashes, and domestic inflation spikes there too. Countries with weak institutions might see hyperinflation or collapse (some smaller fragile states could fail economically). China: Very interesting in this scenario – high global inflation could initially help erode China’s dollar debt (if any) and raise their export prices, but if the U.S. slump in late 2020s hits, that hurts their exports. Also, if Fed hikes cause global recession, China’s attempts to grow might be foiled. They could either import inflation if they keep the yuan weak, or fight it at the cost of growth. Perhaps China in this scenario tries to ride it out but ends with mediocre growth of ~3% and inflation of maybe ~4% (higher than the target, low by global standards). Socially, inflation is sensitive (food prices can cause unrest), so they likely use price controls which cause distortions. If global chaos is high, China might find an opportunity to expand its influence (lending to countries cut off from the West or pushing RMB usage), but also a risk (if developed markets demand drops or if they face property/infrastructure bust from high rates). Commodity producers: ironically, some places like Middle East oil states could benefit from sustained high oil prices – they’d have a windfall (like in 1970s OPEC did). They might accumulate huge wealth (though inflation could erode some, but they can convert to gold or assets). That might shift global power – petrostates become wealthier relative to West. 


Bottom line (Long-Term High Inflation/Distress): By 2029, this scenario has either forced a drastic reckoning (with central banks finally squashing inflation via brutal recessions, causing a debt crisis but setting stage perhaps for eventual recovery beyond our horizon) or, if not yet resolved, the world is in a continuous high-inflation chaotic state. Key markers: Inflation maybe still ~5%+ in advanced world, policy rates extremely high (or at least were high and caused collapse), global growth very low or negative due to repeated recessions, unemployment higher than in any other scenario at times (maybe double digits at peak), multiple crises (sovereign defaults, bank failures, currency collapses) have occurred. It is a world with significantly higher macro volatility, akin to the worst of the 1970s stagflation meets 1980s debt crisis. The silver lining could be that by punishing inflation so severely, the stage could be set for a new stable period (like after 1983, the Great Moderation began). But that’s beyond 2029 likely; by 2029 we’d be either in the depths of that painful adjustment or still floundering. Probability we assign ~20%, as it requires many policy failures, but it’s not negligible given how the 2020s started with a shock to the system. 

Stock Valuation too high

Long-Term Scenarios Summary: The outcomes by the end of the decade hinge on whether the world successfully rebalances wealth and productivity and anchors inflation. The Base Case (~50%) foresees a reasonably favourable outcome: a return to stable, moderate growth with inflation at target – essentially the problems of the early 2020s get solved through a softish landing and improved productivity. Alternative 1 (~30%) is a deflationary stagnation where those problems are solved too well (inflation extinguished but growth also), leading to secular stagnation akin to Japan. Alternative 2 (~20%) is an inflationary failure case, where problems are not solved until a major crash or not at all by 2029, leaving the global economy unstable and in crisis management mode. These scenarios are in many ways extensions of the medium-term ones – if the soft landing medium-term scenario holds, likely the long term is base case; if the slump scenario holds, long term is Japanification; if stagflation scenario holds, long term is high-inflation regime or crisis. They also highlight interconnected risks: e.g., global dollar liquidity issues are severe in Alt2 long-term (as Fed tightening drains world dollars, causing EM crises), whereas in Alt1 long-term, global liquidity is excessive (pushing yields to zero but not sparking growth). In all scenarios, we drew parallels with historical precedents: the Base Case differs from 2007–09 in that we avoid a financial crash and recover like mid-90s or mid-2000s expansions (with better productivity). Alt1 explicitly parallels Japan post-1990 (and the post-2009 secular stagnation fears, but writ global). Alt2 parallels 1970s stagflation culminating in early-80s high rates and crises (or, if mismanaged further, could even parallel 1930s where policy mistakes led to depression and currency devaluations – though we hope policy lessons would avoid the worst repeats, thus we consider more 1970s/80s like). 

 

(For a quantitative comparison of long-term scenario endpoints, see Table 3 below.) 

Conclusion and Implications 

Across all horizons and regions, our scenarios underscore a few unifying themes derived from the initial arguments: 

  • Central Bank Credibility vs Market Expectations: The tension between central banks’ cautious approach and bond markets’ conviction about future rate cuts is a thread through the short-term. In our base cases, central banks gradually converge toward market expectations (validating a soft landing), whereas in alternative scenarios that tension breaks – either markets were too optimistic (leading to recession when cuts don’t come in time) or central banks lose control (markets expect cuts but inflation prevents them, leading to stagflation). The 2-year yield remains a key barometer: in base case, its drop precedes and correctly signals policy easing; in alt scenarios, it either falls too late (recession hits first) or it jumps back up as markets realise cuts aren’t coming in a sticky inflation environment. 
  • Asset Prices and the Real Economy: The idea that asset prices have been primary drivers of growth rather than mirrors of productivity is validated in the sense that when asset values correct (as in Alt 1 scenarios), the economy loses momentum – e.g., housing wealth declines dampen consumption noticeably. In the base case, a moderate asset correction is actually salutary, preventing bubbles but not causing collapse. By the long term, under base case, we assume an era where productivity growth catches up somewhat to previously inflated asset values (paper wealth), avoiding the need for either a drastic wealth reset or high inflation erasure. In alternatives, we either see that wealth reset (Alt1 long-term stagnation, where asset values drop ~30%+ and stay low) or sustained inflation (Alt2 long-term, where high inflation erodes real values over time but in a chaotic way). 
  • Housing Policy and Wealth Effects: We incorporated the impact of housing policy (deregulation increasing supply) leading to short-term disinflation through reduced wealth. Indeed, in base short-term, we assumed expanded housing supply helps cool prices, subtracting a bit from consumption and inflation (a policy-induced quasi recessionary effect, but mild). This aligns with the notion that easing housing costs can act as a “reverse wealth effect” on demand and thus on inflation. The Capital Economics skepticism aside, our scenario assumes some effect in U.S. – say a few percentage points off home values leading to a few tenths off inflation. Over the medium term, increased housing supply is a net positive (improving productivity of labour via mobility, etc., and keeping shelter inflation low). So housing policy is one lever that differentiates scenarios: base case includes successful housing supply measures (keeping a lid on housing inflation), whereas alt scenarios either see too little (stagflation scenario, where housing remains unaffordable and a source of cost pressure) or housing crash (recession scenario, where wealth loss is severe). 
  • Consumer Psychology and Narratives: We highlighted how recession narratives can become self-fulfilling – in Alt 1 short-term, media gloom triggers a pullback in spending that precipitates the downturn. In base case, narrative shifts to soft-landing optimism, supporting confidence. Shiller’s “narrative economics” is clearly at play: what consumers hear (R-word index, etc.) influences their spending beyond fundamentals. By the long term, in the base scenario, presumably positive narratives about innovation and stability encourage investment, whereas in stagnation scenario, a narrative of secular decline could set in, reinforcing high saving/low spending. Policymakers need to manage expectations – forward guidance and clear communication are tools to shape these narratives. The Richmond Fed research noted recessions without clear causes often are explained by cascading negative sentiment – avoiding that requires careful messaging when risks arise. 
  • Eurodollar System and Global Liquidity: Our scenarios account for the global offshore dollar: in base cases, no major hiccups – Fed swap lines and cautious global bank behavior keep things smooth. But in Alt 1 (recession), we see a potential dollar funding crunch which the Fed alleviates with swap lines, reinforcing that the Eurodollar system, while outside Fed’s direct reach, ultimately still needed the Fed as lender of last resort in crises. In Alt 2 (stagflation), a different problem emerges: Fed tightening sucks dollars out, stressing eurodollar markets; or if Fed doesn’t tighten enough, perhaps offshore dollar creation runs rampant initially, adding to inflation – but when it reverses, it’s chaotic. The independence of the Eurodollar system from domestic U.S. monetary control implies that even if the Fed is easing, global dollar credit can contract (if foreigners pull back) – as happened in e.g. 2008 and 2020. We saw in Q4 2023, dollar credit actually dipped even with Fed tight , showing non-linear effects. In stagnation scenario, we posited global liquidity paradox: plenty of base money but low credit creation (pushing on string), whereas in high-inflation scenario perhaps too much credit chasing too few goods globally (exacerbated by demand for safe assets making controlling long yields hard). Either way, coordination via BIS or Fed swap lines is crucial to prevent the Eurodollar plumbing from freezing. 
  • Safe Asset Demand and Yield Curves: One striking point: yield curve behavior in our scenarios is influenced heavily by safe asset demand. Base case assumes continued strong demand keeps long yields relatively low, despite high issuance – this is why even by 2029 we had 10y ~3%. This is aligned with the structural demand for safety literature (convenience yield). In Alt 1 stagnation, safe asset demand is extreme (flight to safety), so yields are rock-bottom (maybe even negative in real terms). In Alt 2, that demand is overshadowed by inflation fear – investors start to shun even Treasuries unless compensated with high nominal yields, until central banks restore credibility. These differences underline that the yield curve is not just about expected short rates but about safety premia – e.g., in Alt 1, Treasuries might yield far less than nominal GDP growth (like in 2010s or in Japan) because of a big safety premium, whereas in Alt 2, they yield more than growth (like early 80s) due to lost trust and less effective safe asset demand. Also, structural demand (pensions, insurers in aging societies) remains a downward force on yields in all but the worst inflation scenario – even in stagflation, at some point, those institutions would step in to buy long bonds if yields are high enough, helping eventually cap yields (albeit at a higher equilibrium). Treasury issuance vs demand: historically, heavy issuance in 2020s was absorbed partly due to QE and private demand; in future, if QT continues (shrinking Fed holding) and foreigners don’t buy as much (if dollar’s role diminishes slightly or if others need cash at home), there is a risk yields rise – but if global aging and risk aversion persist, domestic institutions might fill the gap, as per safe asset shortage theory. 
  • Interpreting Inflation Data & Policy Mistakes: We drew analogies to 2008’s misinterpreted inflation spike – ECBs 2008 hike is the classic cautionary tale. In our scenarios, the base case has central banks avoiding such mistakes (e.g., not over-tightening on a one-off commodity spike) – for instance, the Fed in 2024–25 base case holds steady despite a temporary energy uptick, recalling 2008’s lesson. Alt 2, however, is basically the scenario of repeating 1970s-style mistakes: easing too soon on some positive signals, then inflation roaring back – akin to Fed in 1974–1978 period, or like some argue the Fed did in 2021 (though that was a shorter mistake quickly corrected in 2022). Misreading data (like seeing transitory factors as permanent or vice versa) can cause yield spikes – we mentioned 2009 when QE1 caused inflation fears and a yield surge. In stagflation scenario, we see yields spike when policy credibility is doubted. The yield curve’s predictive power also could be misread: e.g., if term premia distort the curve (safe asset demand flattening it even if recession risk is real, or steepening it if inflation risk dominates). All scenarios highlight that good data analysis is vital – central banks need to discern underlying trend inflation vs noise. Right now, the risk is either they think inflation is beat and cut too early (1970s error) or they fight shadows and cause undue recession (1937 Fed error for example). Our base case assumes they thread the needle well – not an easy task, but achievable with improved models and communications. 


In summary, our probability-weighted analysis suggests a cautiously optimistic base case (soft landing to steady growth) but with significant tail risks on either side. Policymakers should remain vigilant: continue monitoring wealth indicators relative to productivity (to spot bubbles), address housing supply for structural inflation relief, shape public expectations (to avoid self-fulfilling downturns), coordinate internationally on liquidity provision, and be ready to act decisively either to prevent deflationary spirals or to break inflation if it becomes entrenched. History (2007–2009 and 1970s in particular) offers lessons: proactive and flexible policy can mean the difference between a mild adjustment and a decade of pain. At present (2025), leading indicators like the yield curve and inflation breakevens imply markets still broadly expect a return to low inflation and some easing. That aligns with our base case. But as our alternative scenarios illustrate, there is a non-trivial chance that either a deflationary or inflationary regime could take hold if any of the interconnected factors – policy, market psychology, global credit flows – shift adversely. The prudent approach for investors and policymakers is to prepare for a range of outcomes, with contingency plans for the extremes (e.g., capability to deploy large fiscal stimulus in a slump, or coordinated tightening and income policies if inflation resurges). Diversification, stress-testing portfolios, and keeping an eye on cross-market signals (like commodity prices, wage growth, and international funding stresses) will be crucial in navigating the next few years. 

Ultimately, while our base case envisions a relatively benign macroeconomic environment over the next four years (the U.S. and Europe achieving soft landings and Asia continuing to grow), the probability-weighted assessment acknowledges roughly a 40-50% chance of more extreme scenarios – either a significant downturn or a stagflationary period. This underscores the need for risk management at every level, from central banks (who must balance dual risks of inflation and recession) to investors (who should hedge both tail risks). The interplay of asset markets, policy decisions, and public expectations will determine which path we follow. By synthesising the arguments and data, we have outlined the signposts to watch: yield curves (inversion or steepening), inflation trends vs targets, asset price alignment with productivity, consumer sentiment surveys, and global dollar funding conditions. These will signal which scenario the economy is gravitating toward, allowing timely adjustments to strategy. 

The scenarios provided here, with their probabilities, quantitative forecasts, and narratives for the U.S., Europe, and Asia, offer a roadmap for thinking about the future. They combine fundamental analysis (output gaps, policy reaction functions) with market-implied insights (like FedWatch probabilities, breakeven inflation rates, etc.) to ensure consistency. While reality may not fit neatly into any one scenario, this range of outcomes equips decision-makers with a mental framework to anticipate and respond to the macro-financial landscape of the coming years. By drawing parallels to historical episodes such as 2007–2009, we’ve also highlighted where the present situation is similar and where it differs – for instance, banks are stronger now , but inflation is higher; policy toolkits are broader (e.g., QE) but debts are larger. This means new crises might not look exactly like the last, and responses will need to be calibrated accordingly. 

In conclusion, the next 3–6 months are likely to be a delicate balancing act (with our base case leaning towards a modest soft landing), the 2-year horizon will reveal whether 2024’s adjustments set the stage for enduring stability or not, and the 4-year horizon will reflect the cumulative impact of policy choices and structural shifts. By assigning probabilities and detailing these scenarios, we aim to inform strategic planning that is resilient under uncertainty – whether one is setting monetary policy, fiscal budgets, or portfolio allocations, it’s wise to keep in mind the alternative paths the economy might take and the early signals that will indicate which path we’re on. As the saying goes, “Forecasting is difficult, especially about the future.” But scenario analysis with clear logic and data can better prepare us for whatever the future holds.